ARCHIVÉ - Transcription
Cette page Web a été archivée dans le Web
L’information dont il est indiqué qu’elle est archivée est fournie à des fins de référence, de recherche ou de tenue de documents. Elle n’est pas assujettie aux normes Web du gouvernement du Canada et elle n’a pas été modifiée ou mise à jour depuis son archivage. Pour obtenir cette information dans un autre format, veuillez communiquer avec nous.
Offrir un contenu dans les deux langues officielles
Prière de noter que la Loi sur les langues officielles exige que toutes publications gouvernementales soient disponibles dans les deux langues officielles.
Afin de rencontrer certaines des exigences de cette loi, les procès-verbaux du Conseil seront dorénavant bilingues en ce qui a trait à la page couverture, la liste des membres et du personnel du CRTC participant à l'audience et la table des matières.
Toutefois, la publication susmentionnée est un compte rendu textuel des délibérations et, en tant que tel, est transcrite dans l'une ou l'autre des deux langues officielles, compte tenu de la langue utilisée par le participant à l'audience.
TRANSCRIPT OF PROCEEDINGS BEFORE
THE CANADIAN RADIO‑TELEVISION AND
TELECOMMUNICATIONS COMMISSION
TRANSCRIPTION DES AUDIENCES DEVANT
LE CONSEIL DE LA RADIODIFFUSION
ET DES TÉLÉCOMMUNICATIONS CANADIENNES
SUBJECT:
Review of price cap framework /
Examen du cadre de plafonnement des prix
HELD AT:
TENUE À:
Conference Centre
Centre de conférences
Outaouais Room
Salle Outaouais
140 Promenade du Portage
140, Promenade du Portage
Gatineau, Quebec
Gatineau (Québec)
October 18, 2006
Le 18 octobre 2006
Transcripts
In order to meet the requirements of the
Official Languages
Act, transcripts of proceedings before the
Commission will be
bilingual as to their covers, the listing of
the CRTC members
and staff attending the public hearings, and
the Table of
Contents.
However, the aforementioned publication is the
recorded
verbatim transcript and, as such, is taped and
transcribed in
either of the official languages, depending on
the language
spoken by the participant at the public
hearing.
Transcription
Afin de rencontrer les exigences de la Loi sur
les langues
officielles, les procès‑verbaux pour le Conseil
seront
bilingues en ce qui a trait à la page
couverture, la liste des
membres et du personnel du CRTC participant à
l'audience
publique ainsi que la table des
matières.
Toutefois, la publication susmentionnée est un
compte rendu
textuel des délibérations et, en tant que tel,
est enregistrée
et transcrite dans l'une ou l'autre des deux
langues
officielles, compte tenu de la langue utilisée
par le
participant à l'audience
publique.
Canadian Radio‑television and
Telecommunications Commission
Conseil de la radiodiffusion et des
télécommunications canadiennes
Transcript / Transcription
Review of price cap framework /
Examen du cadre de plafonnement des prix
BEFORE / DEVANT:
Richard French
Chairperson / Président
Helen del Val
Commissioner / Conseillère
Elizabeth Duncan
Commissioner / Conseillère
Andrée Noël
Commissioner / Conseillère
Stuart Langford
Commissioner / Conseiller
ALSO PRESENT / AUSSI
PRÉSENTS:
Marielle Giroux-Girard
Secretary / Secrétaire
Bob Noakes
Staff Team Leader /
Chef d'équipe du
personnel
Stephen Millington
Legal Counsel /
Rachelle Frenette
Conseillers juridiques
HELD AT:
TENUE À:
Conference Centre
Centre de conférences
Outaouais Room
Salle Outaouais
140 Promenade du Portage
140, Promenade du Portage
Gatineau, Quebec
Gatineau (Québec)
October 18, 2006
Le 18 octobre 2006
- iv -
TABLE DES MATIÈRES / TABLE OF CONTENTS
PAGE /
PARA
*ARGUMENT by / PLAIDOIRIE
par:
The Companies
1387 /
9528
MTS Allstream
1406 /
9606
TELUS Communications Company
1423 /
9685
The Competitors
1437 /
9763
The Consumer Groups
1460 /
9842
L'Union des consommateurs
1479 /
9943
BCOAPO et al
1489 / 10001
The City of Calgary
1497 / 10048
- v -
EXHIBITS / PIÈCES JUSTICATIVES
No.
PAGE /
PARA
TELUS‑16 Response to
undertaking,
TELUS Undertaking No. 2
regarding high‑speed
internet services in
TELUS' serving territory
1509 / 10092
TELUS‑17 Follow‑up to
TELUS'
Undertaking No. 3
regarding services with
frozen rate treatment basket 1509 /
10093
Gatineau, Quebec / Gatineau (Québec)
‑‑‑ Upon resuming on Wednesday, October
18, 2006
at 0859 / L'audience reprend
le mercredi
18 octobre 2006 à
0859
9520
THE CHAIRPERSON: Order,
please. À l'ordre, s'il vous
plaît.
9521
Ladies and gentlemen, we are going to proceed now with oral final
argument by the various parties.
9522
Before we do so, I don't doubt that madam secretary probably has a
certain number of things to say to you but I must first discharge an important
obligation and responsibility in wishing Mr. Bob Noakes.
‑‑‑ Laughter / Rires
9523
THE CHAIRPERSON: Mr. Noakes
is one of the many unsung citizens of the CRTC who ensure that these
commissioners don't make bigger fools of themselves than is absolutely
necessary. He does it with
particular efficiency and self‑effacement and we appreciate it very
much.
9524
Madam secretary.
9525
THE SECRETARY: Good morning,
everyone.
9526
We are at the final phase of the hearing, the final arguments. I will invite the counsel for The
Companies to come forward, please.
9527
Counsel Denis.
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9528
MR. HENRY: Thank you, madame
secretary.
9529
Good morning, Mr. Chairman and Commissioners.
9530
Mr. Chairman, this proceeding finds us in times of great change. Now, before you think this is a familiar
refrain that you may have heard from the ILECs many times before, I would ask
you to reflect on what is different about this proceeding from prior price cap
proceedings.
9531
First, we have actual widespread competitive entry in the local market,
no longer anticipated but this time real.
9532
We have cable companies themselves acknowledging that the market is
competitive. They are quite
comfortable with their role and prospects of the
marketplace.
9533
We have the Commission itself having recently found that competition is
more deeply rooted than it was thought just months ago.
9534
We have a Telecom Policy Review Panel report that has found massive
changes in the competitive landscape in Canada.
9535
We have federal government policy‑makers having found that VoIP has
transformed the nature and extent of competition in local
telephony.
9536
We have a Draft Policy Direction tabled in Parliament calling for a
greater reliance on market forces.
9537
We have a multitude of third party industry observers no longer debating
whether entrants will be successful, but rather debating just how the ILECs will
be able to adapt.
9538
Against this backdrop it may seem that your task has never been more
challenging, and that is to design a regulatory framework that will
take effect mid next year and progress sometime into the
future.
9539
But I suggest to you that all these facts actually make your task easier
than it was in the past, and that is because you can now have faith in market
forces where entry has occurred and retain upward pricing constraints only in
areas where that entry may not yet have occurred.
9540
Mr. Chairman, that is exactly what our proposal is designed to
do.
9541
For the first time you are hearing from our competitors of their
impressive growth that they have achieved with their telephony offerings. You have heard that they have already
rolled their telephony services out to the majority of their cable companies,
and that their intention is to have at or near 100 percent coverage
wherever their cable infrastructure will support digital
telephony.
9542
To underline the importance of telephony for the future of cable
companies, Mr. Brazeau for Shaw noted that digital telephone is Shaw's
number one investment and new product strategy focus for the
company.
9543
Rogers and Vidéotron, for their part, provide local exchange services in
both residential markets and business markets, and they have acknowledged that
they have advantages not previously enjoyed by competitors in the local
market. These advantages include
their full suite of services, broadcast distribution, Internet access, and in
some cases wireless, as well as their telephony services.
9544
Other significant advantages are their existing customer base in the
millions and their well‑known household brands. They have stated that competition will
deliver the benefits that were once thought achievable only by price cap
formulas. For instance, the
competitors have noted that for the next price cap period competition can be
relied upon to share productivity gains and that:
"Consumers are becoming more
comfortable with offerings from competitors as competitors establish track
records as reliable providers of telephone service." (As read)
9545
Further, they have stated that the intensity of competition in the local
residential market by May ‑‑ that is May of next year ‑‑ will
be such that consumers will have lower‑cost competitive alternatives
that will put downward pressure on ILEC rates.
9546
The market conditions we face today present us with an opportunity, an
opportunity to relax regulation because market conditions will supply the
pricing discipline and to focus regulation only where it is
required.
9547
Furthermore, in deciding on the next price cap framework I would urge you
not to attempt to guess what ILECs might need to do in the market during the
next price cap period and then attempt to devise precise regulatory measures
designed to give only enough flexibility to be able to do what is
predicted. Quite simply, it is not
possible to know what will be necessary in the future, particularly in an
industry this dynamic.
9548
Regulation can have unintended consequences, all the more so, in today's
uncertain and unpredictable environment.
9549
When our proposed alternative facilities test is satisfied, barriers to
entry are unambiguously low. In
recognition of this fact and the many supply and demand conditions present,
services should be uncapped to let market conditions determine
prices.
9550
I do not propose to repeat the mechanics of our uncapping test, I think
by now you know it well, but I do want to reiterate that uncapping is not
forbearance. It falls well short of
it. All competitor safeguards,
including the imputation test will remain in place. Restrictions and promotions,
win‑backs and bundling will be unaffected by this proposal. Tariffs will still be filed and approval
will be required before tariff changes can be implemented.
9551
In the discussion of uncapping the issue of orphan customers arose. The term "orphan customer", as I
understand it at least, refers to a customer who would not have alternatives
available even though an exchange in which he is located passes the test and is
therefore uncapped.
9552
Now, the record shows that the orphan customer phenomenon can be
expected to be rare. The
forbearance decision concluded that where cable companies enter an exchange they
generally cover in its entirety, thus choosing the exchange as the area for
the alternative facilities test as we propose can be expected to minimize
the occurrence of any orphan customers.
9553
Moreover, to the extent there are any orphan customers, they would not
necessarily be left unprotected.
9554
Mr. Grieve for TELUS noted that it would be very difficult, if not
impossible, to identify these customers.
That tells us something important.
It tells us that even if the ILEC wanted to single out these customers
for some special treatment compared to others in the exchange, the ILEC would
not do it.
9555
As a result, it would be unreasonable to reject the alternatives
facilities test and its consequent uncapping on the basis that there is a
possibility, albeit exceedingly small, that some customers could in theory be
harmed.
9556
We submit that it is far better to rely on market forces where possible
than it is to continue to impose price cap regulations based on remote
possibilities and theoretical fears.
That would not be focusing regulation only where it is required or
relying on market forces to the maximum extent possible.
9557
Another feature of our proposal, Mr. Chairman, is the uncapping of
discretionary services. These
services do not need to be capped.
9558
First of all, in many exchanges they may be
competitive.
9559
Second, they are discretionary in nature. It is for this second reason really that
discretionary tiers of television service were never price regulated by this
Commission.
9560
Society does not place the same value on these services as they do on
connectivity services. Society has
an expectation, I grant you, that most people rich and poor can be reachable by
some form of telecommunications.
But we don't have the same expectation that everyone should have
three‑way calling or call return or call waiting. You have heard that many other
jurisdictions are deciding not to regulate prices of discretionary
services.
9561
As Ms Griffin‑Muir of MTS Allstream stated, you don't need to take these
services to get basic telephone services.
Even the Consumer Groups suggest a more relaxed treatment for these
services. They propose a cap of
inflation +3 percent.
9562
Let me turn to the rules that should be in place when and where
price constraints are warranted.
9563
We have proposed individual rate element constraints of 5 percent
for residential services and 10 percent for business services, as
have been used since 1998 and, more importantly, a freeze on average
prices overall in the residence and bus baskets.
9564
This will significantly constrain prices and is offered as assurance that
affordability of service will not be jeopardized. In fact, assuming inflation continues in
the future, this proposal offers customers price decreases in real
terms.
9565
In previous price cap plans, the I‑X formula ‑‑ that is the
difference between inflation and a productivity target ‑‑ has been used to
cap aggregate price changes. In the
current period, I‑X has also capped some competitor services individually and
some business services.
9566
The formula is not needed to protect affordability. Clearly prices in Canada are affordable
by any standard.
9567
Further, using the formula would undoubtedly influence price levels in a
way that may differ from the competitive outcome.
9568
We have concluded that it is best to step away from formulaic approaches,
as many other jurisdictions are doing, and we propose this despite the
decreasing level of productivity to be expected in the next price cap
period. That lower productivity
level would actually allow for price increases in capped areas if the formula
were applied.
9569
Nevertheless, if the Commission were to decide to employ an X‑factor in
the next period, then it is essential that it take into account not only the
historical productivity trend, but also those factors that can be expected to
cause deviations from that trend.
We have shown that future line losses, a phenomenon not captured in the
historical trend, and other competition‑related factors will result in an X of
minus 0.5 percent.
9570
TELUS has provided an expected X value that also would allow price
increases. MTS Allstream, for their
part in the Consumer Groups, have also proposed values of X. In so doing, MTS Allstream has
acknowledged that line losses going forward can indeed reduce productivity
improvement performance relative to its proposed X rate.
9571
The Consumer Groups have ignored this reality. The proposal of the Consumer Groups for
a 6 percent X‑factor is riddled with other flaws, too many to discuss here this
morning. Suffice it to say, it is
built on a total factor productivity, TFP, measure developed not in this price
cap proceeding, not in the last price cap proceeding, but the one before that, a
measure that includes data for a period that ended over a decade ago and it is a
measure that also reflects productivity associated with services that are no
longer capped or even regulated by the Commission.
9572
The Commission has already rejected use of a total factor productivity
measure for good reason in its last price cap decision and you have no credible
evidence before you to justify a change in that position.
9573
Now, the Consumer Groups' proposal, having started with that number, then
goes on to attempt to adjust this outdated total factor productivity measure
with supposedly more current U.S. information, which is not only built on faulty
theories and assumptions, but also frankly on made‑up numbers devoid of any
empirical validity.
9574
As just one example, you will recall the difference between Bell Canada
data and some U.S. data contained in one of Dr. Roycroft's studies regarding
DSL. Now, Mr. Chairman, it
only takes a cursory review of Dr. Roycroft's analysis to reveal its flaws. What Bell Canada presented was real data
from real‑life experience. What Dr.
Roycroft presented was constructed numbers based on equipment costs he pulled
out of trade press articles. And
even then, he only looked at one piece of equipment, the DSLAM, and just assumed
a small token amount $25 capital I think it was and $1.50 per month expense
supposedly to reflect all the myriad other costs that one could expect when
introducing a new service based on a new technology. Things like truck rolls to conditioned
loops.
9575
I think we all remember the early days of DSL when there were all kinds
of that going on, truck rolls to install services long before things were plug
and play and to the extent they were plug and play, we had activity desks,
people calling in to figure out how it worked, change their password, truck
rolls to maintain or repair services, other equipment costs including cabinets
to house the DSLAM equipment, power to the cabinets. We had to extend fibre deeper in the
network to reach these DSLAMs, we had sales and marketing expenses, the list
goes on.
9576
Mr. Chairman, his numbers are simply not credible on their
face.
9577
There are other serious problems with Dr. Roycroft's proposal. Incredible as it may sound, Dr. Roycroft
confirmed on Monday that he is proposing that any forborne services remain
subject to his price cap framework for a period of five years following
forbearance.
9578
This would have the perverse effect of allowing prices in non‑forborne
areas to rise higher than they otherwise would be allowed to, not to mention the
fact that it would effectively stretch the effects of the next price cap regime
well past his proposed four‑year period to potentially up to nine years, I think
the year 2016 by my calculations.
9579
Let me now turn to the issue of price de‑averaging. The current restriction on further price
de‑averaging harms customers, it keeps prices higher than they would be if the
ILEC were able to meet competition where it exists. Customers are deprived of the best
offers that could be made to them and this harms the competitive process as
well.
9580
Now, let us look at a real example.
In Ottawa Rogers offers a line with five features and unlimited North
American long‑distance for $66.15.
That compares to Cogeco's rate of $54.99 for the same services in
Hamilton. Now if Bell were to set
its prices to compete with Rogers in Ottawa it would not be able to compete with
Cogeco in Hamilton. On the other
hand, to compete with Cogeco's price in Hamilton, Bell Canada would have to
lower the price in Ottawa by $11.00 more than would be required to compete with
Rogers there.
9581
Now the fundamental problem is the de‑averaging rule does not allow the
ILEC to price in accordance with market conditions. The ILEC is given perverse
incentives. For example, to either
compete less vigorously in some areas or not at all. And in either event, the important point
is this sends wrong pricing signals to the market and it distorts the
competitive market outcome.
9582
The incentive properties of the de‑averaging prohibition are likely to
keep prices unchanged, even in the face of competition in one part of the
band. Lowering price throughout the
band will often be too costly. It
is this incentive that is the intended consequence, of course, of those who seek
to preserve the de‑averaging prohibition, as MTS Allstream confirmed in its
testimony.
9583
Now Mr. Watt of Rogers acknowledged that de‑averaging prices in a
band by province makes sense because, as he put it, the telephone companies are,
"facing different market situations."
Now I suggest to you that that is a very telling admission because, of
course, the telephone companies are facing different market situations within a
band as well. Competition is not
uniform, it doesn't occur in a neat and tidy fashion defined by bands. Different competitors have different
offers and even the same competitor has different offers in different
areas.
9584
I suggest to you that it follows from Dr. Watt's reasoning that
de‑averaging prices within a band to meet the different market situations within
that band is equally warranted.
9585
Now our competitors have called de‑averaging anticompetitive. I think they tend to depict anything
that increases or intensifies competition as anticompetitive. But there is nothing anticompetitive
about de‑averaging. De‑averaging is
not, of course, prohibited or restricted by the Competition Act. The cable company is a service that
offer a special price to a group of customers as long as those customers are not
defined, in geographic terms, would not be prohibited by the current
restriction. This would allow they
claim, or I think some of them claim, a special price discount to students if we
wanted or a special price to new customers.
9586
So apparently there are some de‑averaging practices that even the cable
companies would not label anticompetitive as they use the
term.
9587
MTS Allstream indicated that whether de‑averaging would be considered
anticompetitive depends on the facts of the situation.
9588
Mr. Chairman, it is not clear what tips the balance in their
minds. When is de‑averaging
anticompetitive and when is it not?
What is the defining characteristic of the practice that makes it
anticompetitive to them? These
questions have not been answered by them.
Of course, the real answer is that price de‑averaging is not
anticompetitive at all.
9589
Now the competitors, I am sure, will likely try to advance an economic
theory, and one that is not universally held by the way, that de‑averaging is
not found in perfectly competitive markets. What they fail to say, however, is that
perfectly competitive markets do not exist in reality and that in reality the
consequence is that de‑averaging is common in all industries. Our witness panel gave numerous examples
of de‑averaging in telephony, in other lines of businesses and indeed in many
other industries, airline, you name it.
9590
As for the cable companies, and this was very interesting, their story
changed dramatically as the hearing progressed. First of all, their counsel first
suggested that price de‑averaging is not happening and that was the first theory
of the case. Then they suggested,
well de‑averaging is a practice of monopolists but it's not found in competitive
markets. But when their witness
panel got on the stand they had quite a different story. When confronted with an example of
de‑averaging in their wireless business, they retorted that this was because
wireless was a robustly competitive market. The contradiction between their theory
and their practice was striking.
9591
In further discussions, it became clear that de‑averaging examples abound
in all their lines of business, including Internet, broadcast distribution and
telephony offerings. There is only
one reasonable conclusion, de‑averaging is a normal feature of
markets.
9592
Indeed, this Commission has so found in its wireless decision 2003‑26,
which was discussed with Mr. Watt and actually Commissioner Noël as well
the Commission concluded that targeted offers are to be expected in robustly
competitive markets.
9593
Try as they might, not one of the cable companies that appeared before
you could offer an adequate public policy justification for the regulatory
protection they seek to preserve in the form of the de‑averaging
restriction. It became very
evidence during the discussion with the panel, the commissioners in particular,
that the de‑averaging prohibition was all about furthering the economic
self‑interests of the cable companies.
9594
I was struck, Mr. Chairman, when I listened to your questions from
several of you. Your questions were
about the effect on consumers.
Almost universally their answers were about themselves and only
themselves. The discussion exposed
their argument as an infant industry.
Without debating whether infant industry protection us ever justified, it
certainly has no place in the current environment when you consider just who
these supposed infants are.
9595
Now counsel for The Competitors also questioned whether the de‑averaging
restrictions really matter if The Competitors did not engage in
de‑averaging. Well frankly, whether
or not they do it and whether or not other competitors choose to do it is not
really the point, although it is clear that they do. The relevant question is whether
customers are harmed if de‑averaging is prevented or curtailed by regulation,
and the answer is that they are.
9596
Let me turn finally, very briefly, to the issue of income trusts and
their implications for regulated prices.
An income trust arrangement should not lead to an adjustment in
prices. It is a fundamental
principle of price cap regulation that the consequences of initiatives taken by
a company should lie entirely with the company and its investors. To do otherwise would blunt and possibly
fully defeat the incentives that are the intended objectives of price cap
regulation.
9597
In any event, the income trust arrangements of interest here are
nonrecurring events that fall within the present price cap period. So any gains that may be associated with
them should not affect the future price cap period.
9598
But secondly, it is not at all clear that these arrangements result in
any material gains, and there is material on the record, I think, that we filed
on behalf of uh.. Bell Aliant in that regard. So therefore, even if the Commission
were to take them into account, any consequent price adjustments can be expected
to be small.
9599
Now, Mr. Chairman, this is a somewhat complex issue I will confess
and I don't propose to go into more detail here. I can just assure you that we will be
addressing it in much more detail in our written final
argument.
9600
One last word on a related issue, however, and I would just like to
address the question posed by Commissioner Langford regarding the likely outcome
on prices if the government were to introduce a tax increase to take into
account the tax leakage arising from income trusts.
9601
In this eventuality, we would not request a change to the price caps in
effect. Any such tax would be
economy‑wide, that is it would not be directed at the telecommunications
industry exclusively and therefore would not be an appropriate exogenous
adjustment under the current rules.
Further, The Companies have proposed that for the upcoming price cap
period only Commission decisions would qualify for exogenous
treatment.
9602
Mr. Chairman, there are many other details that will be discussed in
our proposal and throughout this hearing and I cannot attempt to do them justice
here this morning. So I will just
come to a close by commending to you our written final argument and reply yet to
be filed.
9603
I wish you and your fellow commissioners well in your deliberations. On behalf of my colleagues, I would also
like to thank you and your fellow commissioners, Commission counsel, Commission
staff and the hearing secretary for the consideration that has been shown to all
parties.
9604
Thank you very much, Mr. Chairman.
9605
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you, Counsel Denis.
‑‑‑ Pause
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9606
THE CHAIRPERSON: Counsellor?
9607
MR. KOCH: Thank you, Mr. Chairman,
Commissioners.
9608
In this proceeding, in our view, the Commission must confirm where
appropriate pricing flexibility for the ILECs ends and inappropriate pricing
flexibility begins. It is not an
easy task. But in other words, how
much pricing flexibility is necessary and how much flexibility is too
much?
9609
The answer to this question, we believe, begins with establishing the
appropriate objectives for the next price cap regime. The first objective MTS Allstream has
identified is promoting competition.
Competition is emerging, but the transition to competition is far from
complete. The market for PES, or
PES I will call it, is not yet workably competitive. Demand and other conditions fall short
of the Commission's own forbearance criteria. In our submission, the price cap regime
should not be permitted to serve as a Trojan horse that undermines this recently
established regime.
9610
The price cap applicable to retail services, also in our view, cannot be
considered in a vacuum. The terms
and conditions under which wholesale services are provided should be considered
in tandem.
9611
The second objective MTS Allstream has identified is protecting
consumers. Where market power
persists and forbearance criteria have not yet been met, in our submission,
upward price controls must be retained.
These controls should include a reasonable estimate of productivity that
reflects market conditions anticipated during the next price cap period. In our view, the basket structure can
also be greatly simplified without harming consumers. The third objective MTS Allstream has
identified is increasing reliance on market forces. Passing on predicted efficiencies to
customers should not go so far, in our view, as mandating price reductions that
might impede competition or may simply be unnecessary in light of emerging
competitive market forces.
9612
We are also of the view the case has not been made for the requirement of
ILECs to de‑average rates within the same rate band. It is important, as I indicated at the
outset, to distinguish between appropriate and inappropriate pricing
flexibility, otherwise ILECs will be able to take advantage of their dominance
to control the pace of competitive entry or, and I think this is key, to
selectively bestow the benefits of imperfect competition on only a subset of
consumers.
9613
The combined effect, in our submission, of removing the prohibition
against de‑averaging and uncapping services will be to undercut the forbearance
criteria and damage the development of competition.
9614
The fourth and final objective MTS Allstream has identified is reducing
the regulatory burden. We are of
the view that price cap regulation can be streamlined by removing discretionary
services and bundles from the cap without prejudicing the goal of affordability
of stand‑alone PES.
9615
I will try to distil the remainder of my remarks into three topics. The three I would like to cover, the
state of competition, protecting consumers and the transition to
forbearance.
9616
In the second price cap decision the Commission noted that competition
had not emerged as anticipated. As
we move into the third price cap period competition is emerging in the local
residence market. In the business
market there is relatively more competition, although that competition has been
stagnant for sometime.
9617
We have heard much evidence regarding emerging competition, particularly
competition from the cable companies in the residence market. Emerging competition, however, should
not be confused with the establishment of workable competition, a prerequisite
of which is the elimination of the ILECs' SMP, significant market
power.
9618
The Commission has recently established the criteria for local
forbearance, which are meant to ‑‑ which are meant to measure exactly that,
where the ILECs continue to have SMP and it is important to bear in mind that
those criteria have yet to be met.
9619
Included among the criteria for local forbearance is the requirement that
the ILECs meet important quality of service indicators for competitors. This criterion reflects the importance
of those wholesale regime to competition ‑‑ particularly in the business
market where competition relies on access to underlying infrastructure built
during the monopoly era.
9620
The treatment of wholesale services is not within the scope of this
proceeding, as we have learned, but MTS Allstream is of the view that a price
cap regime that promotes competition is difficult to establish in the absence of
a robust comprehensive wholesale regime.
9621
MTS Allstream looks forward to participating in the Commission's
anticipated proceeding dealing with wholesale access, but in the meantime, we
have proposed that the Commission's current treatment of competitor services be
maintained.
9622
Next, I would like to speak to protecting
consumers.
9623
The Commission, in my view, can be justly proud of its record with regard
to local rates. As the TPR panel
noted, prices for residential and business local services in Canada are the
third and fourth lowest among the O.A.C.S. countries
respectively.
9624
Canada enjoys a local services penetration rate of more than 98
percent. The Commission has
previously recognized penetration is a good measure of
affordability.
9625
In short, we are not here because there is a crisis in the provision of
local service to Canadians. The
areas identified by the T.P.R. panel where Canada is supposedly lagging are, in
fact, broadband and wireless, two market segments that have never been subject
to retail regulation by the Commission.
9626
These are the facts against which the Commission should evaluate extreme
proposals such as that of the consumers to attribute alleged higher productivity
from other service, such as D.S.L. to local services.
9627
Notwithstanding the good state of local rates, we recognize the
Commission statutory mandate to uphold the public interest by ensuring
regulatory mechanisms to protect consumer interests and address the needs of all
users, regardless of location or ability.
9628
We are proposing an X factor of 1.5 percent as a reasonable measure of
productivity growth fro the ILECS as service going
forward.
9629
In the second price cap regime, the Commission adopted a productivity
offset based on an analysis of the marginal costs associated with Bell Canada's
Res PES.
9630
Since that time, there has been a dramatic directional shift in the trend
for access line growth. It is
therefore necessary to adjust the measure that was used the last time to reflect
this movement.
9631
The Consumer Groups' expert, doctor Roycroft, confirmed under
cross‑examination that in an earlier study, he controlled for unusual changes in
output growth, using precisely that, an access line variable as a reasonable
proxy for output growth.
9632
MTS Allstream's expert, Mr. Lefebvre, testified that studies have shown
that between 60 percent and 80 percent of TFP growth has been identified as
being attributable to scale economies.
9633
MTS Allstream took the conservative end of this range and adjusted the
3.5 percent measure by the Commission in the last price cap regime and reduced
it by 60 percent to arrive at a proposed X factor of 1.5
percent.
9634
In the unlikely event that inflation is lower than the X factor, MTS is
proposing that rate reductions not be mandated. We believe that passing on predicted
efficiencies to consumers should not go that far.
9635
Such mandated reductions might impede competitive entry or may simply be
unnecessary in light of emerging competitive market
forces.
9636
We propose that the Commission maintain the individual price constraints
from the last price cap regime of 5 percent for residential services and 10
percent for business services.
9637
And finally, we have proposed modest changes to the basket structure,
including placing high cost serving areas and non high cost serving areas in the
same basket.
9638
I would like to speak to that for a moment.
9639
The separation of high cost serving areas and non high cost serving areas
into separate baskets in the second price cap plan was driven by the
Commission's establishment of a deferral account, in in of itself and our defect
of the Commission's recognition at that time that residence rates should not be
forced downward by a price cap formula in high cost ‑‑ in non high cost
serving areas.
9640
Under our proposal which does not call for mandated price decreases,
there is no longer any need to maintain this separation and as
Mr. Sheppard, witness for MTS Allstream testified, there is no incentive
for the company to raise rates in high cost serving areas as these rates are
significantly below cost and any rate raising would result in a proportionate
reduction of the subsidy.
9641
I would like to move now to the third subject that I wanted to discuss
with you this morning, which is the transition to
forbearance.
9642
Our plan acknowledges changes taking place in the market for local
services and proposes to meet these changes by providing ILECS with significant
additional flexibility.
9643
This additional flexibility takes the form of no‑mandated price
reductions where the X is greater than inflation. It also takes the form of removing
options and features and bundles from the residential basket on the simple logic
that customers have choices not to take these services at all, let alone from
the ILECS.
9644
These measures provide additional flexibility to ILECS in the transition
to forbearance. When thinking about
the extent of pricing flexibility these measures provide, they must also be
added to the transitional flexibility that the Commission has already made
available to the ILECS in the form of the ability to engage in targeted win‑back
activities once they are able to demonstrate a market share loss of 20
percent.
9645
Please do not forget this point.
You have already gone down the road towards providing greater flexibility
on the transition to forbearance.
9646
In our view, all of these transitional measures are appropriate in light
of and can coexist with your recently established forbearance
framework.
9647
That framework again was established to determine when an ILEC continues
to enjoy SMP. As the Commission is
well‑aware, this framework focuses heavily and appropriately so, in our
submission, on the demand characteristics of the market and not solely on
competitive supply.
9648
This framework also establishes the relevant market for the application
of the forbearance criteria as the F.L.R. and not the local
exchange.
9649
Once it achieves forbearance, an ILEC is able to both de‑average rates
within a band and raise rates without any upward
constraint.
9650
Until the Commission's criteria are met, the ILEC continues to have SMP,
however, and in our view, it is both unnecessary and inappropriate to grant the
ILECS additional flexibility that would permit them to take advantage of that
fact.
9651
That is why MTS Allstream opposes Bell and TELUS proposals to remove the
prohibition against de‑averaging.
That is why MTS Allstream opposes Bell and TELUS proposals to
uncap.
9652
The Commission's forbearance criteria have not yet been met in these
instances and those proposals are inappropriate.
9653
The proposals in this regard, in my view, and in my clients' view, are
being driven largely by theory, but the Commission ought not to establish the
regulatory framework based on theory alone.
9654
We submit that those proposing significant changes to the regulatory
regime have the onus of not only demonstrating a pressing need, but also of
satisfying the Commission that the change will not work at cross purposes with
or undermine the Commission's existing framework.
9655
Bell and TELUS, in our submission, have failed on both
counts.
9656
I would like to address de‑averaging specifically as the Commission has
recognized, the rule against de‑averaging within the same rate band does not
prohibit the ILECS from lowering prices to meet competitors. Rather, the rule prohibits the ILECS
from lowering prices selectively and in reliance under
SMP.
9657
So, where is the ILECS beef?
Bell and TELUS have failed to make the case for the ILECS need to
de‑average rates within the same rate band. Even if price discrimination is common
in competitive markets where no firms is able to exercise market power, for
example in the market for wireless services, the local market is not yet such a
market, based on the Commission's own criteria.
9658
Furthermore, as Bell's doctor Krause agreed, in markets where an
incumbent is found to possess SMP, targeted win‑backs are unlikely to improve
consumer surplus or welfare, given that there is no expansion of
output.
9659
No consistent rationale, in my submission, has been provided for the
proposal to remove the prohibition against de‑averaging.
9660
Bell and TELUS witnesses were hard pressed to explain why they wanted or
needed this additional flexibility, whether it be geographic or otherwise, or in
fact how they would use it.
9661
When the question was put to TELUS, its marketing guru Mr. Hansen
stressed that the company generally likes to go out with a consistent marketing
message across a large area. This,
in my submission, does not suggest the need for de‑averaging and the ability to
meet competition in the focused way that the ILECs are
contending.
9662
The TELUS Marketing Panel provided the example of the advertisement in
the Calgary Herald aimed at a number of different communities in different rate
bands but within the same, as they called it, community of
interest.
9663
But this example didn't hang together either, as one of the communities
mentioned, Bragg Creek, is in fact in Band F where prices are already below
costs.
9664
In any event, even if the example worked surely TELUS could use an
asterisk in its advertising to explain that a particular offer may not be
available in all areas. I have
encountered a few of these asterisks myself when looking at their and other
wireless marketing.
9665
Bell and TELUS also failed to make the case for the dangers of
maintaining the prohibition against de‑averaging. Both their economists quoted theory
about inefficient entry and the need to recover their fixed costs, but neither
of these claims have any basis in reality.
Bell and TELUS witnesses were not able to point to either inefficient
entry or their failure to recover their costs, and Bell's evidence regarding the
competitive landscape omits any mention of inefficient
entry.
9666
The prohibition against de‑averaging, again, does not prevent an ILEC
from improving its offer to customers.
Under cross‑examination, Bell's witnesses admitted that the consequences
of making the prohibition were either that all customers in a rate band would
benefit from price reductions designed to meet competition, or competitors would
gain market share if the ILEC chose not to lower its
prices.
9667
De‑averaging is about targeting.
This is inappropriate in a non‑forborne market because the
ILECs have a captive customer base to fund this
targeting.
9668
The issue is not protecting competitors, as Bell alleges; the issue is
protecting customers from being used in this manner to fund the ILECs efforts to
maintain their dominant market share and deter entry.
9669
I would like to turn now to Bell and TELUS' proposal for
uncapping.
9670
If their case for the removal of the prohibition against de‑averaging is
weak, in my submission the case for uncapping is even
weaker.
9671
Commissioner Langford's first question for Bell hit the nail on the
head: Where there is competition
expected to discipline prices why remove the constraint against prices
rising?
9672
We were troubled by the same question and could arrive at only two
possible explanations.
9673
The first is that neither Bell's nor TELUS' test for competitiveness is a
sufficient measure of the ability of competitive market forces alone to
discipline prices throughout the exchange.
The tests proposed are inconsistent with the Commission's forbearance
criteria, which rely heavily on demand characteristics, evidence of rivalrous
behaviour, and found that the local exchange was not the relevant geographic
market.
9674
Mr. Bibic was ready. He was
very well prepared with a long list of explanations why Bell's uncapping test is
not a test for forbearance. But the
fact is that this test is aimed at measuring the very same thing, whether
competition is sufficient to protect the interests of users. That is the language from the
Act.
9675
Permitting the ILECs to uncap services on strict supply criteria, such as
the presence, as they indicated, that fall well short of your own
forbearance criteria, in my respectful submission, would make a mockery of those
same criteria.
9676
The second possible explanation that we had for this proposal is related
to the first. If the
competitiveness test is, as we say, insufficient to identify areas where the
ILECs no long possess SMP, then this flexibility can be used to fund the ILECs
ability to control the pace of competition where that competition does
exist.
9677
Under the Commission's local forbearance rules, the ILECs can only
achieve this type of flexibility where they meet essential criteria, including
the requirement to meet quality of service indicators for services provided by
competitors.
9678
Granting the inappropriate flexibility requested by Bell and TELUS before
these criteria are met will work against the goal of promoting competition and
against the very forbearance criteria established by the Commission a mere
six months ago.
9679
At the beginning of my remarks I stated that the challenge for the
Commission will be drawing the line between appropriate and inappropriate
pricing flexibility. In our
respectful submission, the Bell and TELUS proposals to permit de‑averaging and
uncapped services clearly cross this line and should
be rejected.
9680
On behalf of MTS Allstream I would like to thank you and your staff for
your attention and patience throughout the hearing and wish you all the best in
your deliberations.
9681
Thank you, Mr. Chairman.
9682
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you,
Mr. Koch.
‑‑‑ Pause
9683
THE SECRETARY: We will now
move on with counsel Ryan, please, on behalf of TELUS
Communications.
9684
THE CHAIRPERSON: Mr. Ryan,
on behalf of TELUS.
‑‑‑ Pause
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9685
MR. RYAN: Thank you and good
morning, Mr. Chairman.
9686
Mr. Chairman, the Commission began to introduce competition in
telecommunications markets 25 years ago. It recognized from the outset that a
gradual relaxation of regulation is a natural part of the transition to full
competition. This proceeding
represents another important step in that transitional
process.
9687
The task before you, in our respectful submission, is to design a new
price cap regime that protects consumers from the exercise of market power, but
does so in a way that does not deprive them of the benefits of the competition
that the Commission has been promoting.
9688
A key principle espoused by Dr. Weisman which underpins TELUS'
proposal is that the scope and intensity of regulatory oversight should vary
with market conditions. The
discipline imposed by economic regulation should shade seamlessly into the
greater discipline imposed by increasing competition as market power
declines.
9689
Mr. Chairman, looking back over the last five days of hearings, I think
there are five issues that I could usefully address before you this morning to
help you crystallize your thinking on the issues before
you.
9690
I propose to talk about, therefore, TELUS' competitive presence test; our
proposal for further de‑averaging; our proposal respecting bundling; fourth, our
proposal respecting option services; and, fifth, the X factor. I will also have a few words to say by
way of conclusion about income trusts.
9691
Before I turn to these points let me repeat what we have said several
times before: We are not proposing
forbearance. There is nothing in
our proposal which affects price floors or imputation tests, the tariff approval
requirements for regulated services; restrictions on win‑backs or promotions;
the bundling rules, or CRTC oversight to ensure there is no unjust
discrimination.
9692
Turning first to the competitive presence test.
9693
Consistent with what I have said already about the importance of
regulation varying with market conditions and market power, TELUS has proposed a
competitive presence test. Although
Mr. Koch lumped the Bell and TELUS test together they
differ.
9694
The TELUS test states that where there are at least two alternative
full facilities‑based providers, one of which can be wireless, price regulation
should be eased in recognition of the greater role that market forces will play
in protecting consumers.
9695
The practical effect of TELUS' competitive presence test is that in
exchanges that pass the test customers will have options from four different
carriers available to them: TELUS,
the cable companies telephone service and, since there is rarely one wireless
carrier without there being a second, two wireless
carriers.
9696
Mr. Chairman, you questioned TELUS' inclusion of wireless in the
test. There are two reasons for
this.
9697
First, because three carriers or four will provide more protection
to consumers than a duopoly.
9698
The second reason was given by Janet Yale in her testimony; She said that wireless pricing affects
wireline pricing because of the increasing substitution of wireless for
wireline.
9699
Satisfaction of the competitive presence test, Mr. Chairman, means
that the Commission can rely upon market forces to a greater extent and that
less regulation is required to protect the interests of
consumers.
9700
For services in exchanges that do no pass this test, customers will,
under TELUS' proposal, receive greater regulatory protection to offset less
robust market forces. Prices cannot
increase on average and an individual rate element cannot increase by more than
5 percent.
9701
TELUS' prices will also be constrained by
self‑interest.
9702
TELUS is a provider of a number of telecommunications services. You heard the evidence of Paul
Hansen. He testified that if TELUS
were to raise prices for basic services it would risk losing customers for other
services.
9703
TELUS doesn't want to lose customers. It is much harder and more expensive to
win back a customer than to retain a customer. As Mr. Hansen emphasized, TELUS
will not implement price increases that might damage customer
good‑will.
9704
Some U.S. States have implemented tests that resemble TELUS' competitive
presence test. In fact, in some
cases passing the test leads to forbearance rather than simply relaxed
regulation.
9705
Let me underline that satisfaction of the TELUS competitive presence test
triggers only a relaxation of certain regulatory requirements. It is not a test to determine
forbearance.
9706
As I have already indicated this morning, there was a host of existing
regulatory rules, tariffing win‑back rules, bundling restrictions, promotion
rules, et cetera, that will remain in place.
9707
Uncapping may not adequately describe, Mr. Chairman, what TELUS is
proposing for services and exchanges that pass the competitive presence
test. While TELUS used the
shorthand term "uncapped" to describe what happens to residential local services
in exchanges where the competitive presence test is passed, passing the test
does not mean that all upward pricing constraints are removed. Far from it.
9708
A 5 percent rate element constraint will remain in
place. That is the same rate
element constraint that exists under the current price cap
regime.
9709
Furthermore, customers in exchanges that do not pass the competitive
presence test who might not have any competitive options available to them are
able to ask for the regulated price in the nearest regulated
exchange.
9710
TELUS acknowledges the special issues raised by uncontested customers or
what have sometimes been referred to in this proceeding as orphan customers in
exchanges that meet the competitive presence test.
9711
TELUS will address this subject further in its written argument, but it
is interesting to observe that if TELUS can't identify those customers, as
Mr. Grieve testified is the case, it can't discriminate against them by
targeting them with price increases.
9712
That brings me, Mr. Chairman, to the second subject I propose to
address, and that is further de‑averaging.
9713
I have been asked not to respond to arguments made before you this
morning by counsel that precede me and I will not respond directly,
therefore, to the arguments that Mr. Koch has made on this subject this
morning, but we will do so in our written final argument.
9714
In the meantime, I will satisfy myself with simply outlining for you our
position on the subject.
9715
The TELUS proposal for de‑averaging is better described in fact as a
proposal for further de‑averaging, because rates within bands or even within
exchanges have never been completely averaged. TELUS is asking for a relaxation of the
rule against further de‑averaging in order to allow it to respond more
effectively to competition.
9716
You will remember the testimony of the TELUS marketing panel. They talked about the need for further
de‑averaging across geographic markets that straddle exchanges and
bands.
9717
The prohibition on further de‑averaging means TELUS cannot use normal
channels ‑‑ the example of the Calgary Herald has been cited in evidence
and cited to you again this morning ‑‑ for marketing TELUS services,
because TELUS is not allowed to offer the same price throughout the circulation
area of that newspaper. Because the
paper circulation area cuts across a number of bands and exchanges, TELUS needs
the flexibility to de‑average in order to create a uniform price in the paper
circulation area.
9718
There is another aspect to our request for further
de‑averaging.
9719
There are considerable cost differences within bands and exchanges that
are not recognized in the rate structure left over from the days of monopoly
regulation. You heard from
Mr. Grieve about the very long loops throughout TELUS' ILEC territory that
are priced below cost. TELUS is
asking for the opportunity to address the unhealthy aspects of its historical
rate structure.
9720
Eliminating the rule against further de‑averaging will be good for
consumers, Mr. Chairman.
9721
At present, consumers are deprived of one of the normal benefits of
competition and competitors are left with a comfortable price umbrella that
means they don't have to present their best offers to
customers.
9722
We heard concern during the hearing that de‑averaging would allow ILECs
to raise prices in some areas to make up for competitive price reductions in
others. TELUS' proposal addresses
that concern.
9723
TELUS advocates taking services in areas that pass the competitive
presence test out of the residential basket. That way, if prices for these services
go down the ILECs won't be able to raise prices in the areas that don't meet the
test.
9724
In addition, as Commissioner del Val pointed out, the
section 27(2) rules on unjust discrimination would continue to
apply.
9725
Let me turn next to uncapping of bundles.
9726
Bundles are uncapped under TELUS' proposal, but remember that the very
definition of a bundle is that it is offered at a discount to the sum of the
individual prices of the services offered on a stand‑alone
basis.
9727
Moreover, bundles face significant competitive pressures. The prices are being forced down by
competition.
9728
Removing bundles from the residential services basket is good for
consumers. If they were not
removed and prices of bundles decreased as a result of competitive pressures,
then ILECs would receive headroom to increase the prices of standalone PES
services that do not pass the competitive presence test.
9729
Dr. Roycroft agreed that leaving bundles in the cap would create headroom
for PES price increases in these areas.
9730
Mr. Chairman, you suggested that such a result would be perverse. We agree.
9731
I will turn quickly then to the fourth subject, uncapping of optional
services.
9732
Services should only be regulated if they are essential. Essential services, we say,
are those both used by nearly all consumers and widely regarded as
essential to an acceptable standard of living. To justify regulation of essential
services, they must be supplied on a monopoly basis.
9733
The Commission has already frozen the rates for services such as call
block because of privacy concerns.
However, local optional services are, by their very nature,
discretionary. Discretionary
services compete for discretionary dollars of customers. Optional services are discretionary
because they do not meet the criteria I just described. They are not used by nearly all
consumers and not widely regarded as essential to an acceptable standard of
living.
9734
Now, for the X factor. I
also propose to deal with this subject only briefly.
9735
The need to impose a constraint on prices arises only in areas where the
competitive presence test is not passed.
9736
TELUS is proposing a price freeze for these services rather than the
adoption of an explicit X factor.
Customers will, Mr. Chairman, get greater protection from TELUS'
price freeze than from an explicit X factor because they will be insulated
from the risk of high inflation.
That is a risk that the company will bear.
9737
Should the Commission decide to adopt an explicit X factor, it
should be based on the marginal cost approach adopted in the second price cap
decision. Using that approach
Dr. Bernstein has calculated an X factor in the range of 1.1 to
1.8 percent.
9738
Now, you also have before you the evidence of Dr. Roycroft that that
number should be in the range of 6 percent. But, Mr. Chairman, for reasons you have
already heard this morning, and for others I am about to explain, his approach
to the subject is seriously flawed.
9739
Dr. Roycroft uses data from disparate time periods, 1998 to 1995 for his
calculation of total factor productivity; 1995 to 2004 for the Canadian
economy‑wide multi‑factor productivity calculation; 1992 to 2004 for the input
price differential; 1988 to 2003 for the DSL study which underpins his proposal
respecting the stretch factor.
9740
Second, Dr. Roycroft uses U.S. data in preference to Canadian data in
calculating the input price differential. Use of the Canadian data already
contained in his own evidence to calculate the input price differential would
reduce his X factor by about 2.4 percent.
9741
Dr. Roycroft includes a stretch factor in his calculation, however the
use of a stretch factor is an approach the Commission expressly rejected in
the second price cap decision.
Elimination of the stretch factor would further reduce his X factor
by 1 percent.
9742
So these last two adjustments alone, the one to the input price
differential calculation and to the stretch factor, would already take
Dr. Roycroft's number down from 6 percent to
2.7 percent.
9743
But Dr. Roycroft's greatest sin was to use a TFP
methodology.
9744
As Mr. Henry has already reminded you, TFP is a methodology that was
rejected by the Commission, for good reason, in the last price caps decision,
principally because it does not allow measurement of the productivity of a
subset of services. That is a point
that Dr. Roycroft conceded.
9745
Dr. Roycroft's proposal would take us back to the base number adopted in
the first price cap decision, a number which the Commission declined to use in
the second price cap decision.
9746
Mr. Chairman, I said I would add a few words about income
trusts.
9747
The evidence on the record shows that a trust conversion should not
cause any change in the Commission's approach to price cap regulation. Even if the Commission were to adopt an
explicit X factor, Dr. Bernstein's evidence demonstrates that using
the Commission's accepted marginal cost approach a trust conversion would have
no impact on the level of the X factor.
9748
In any event, it should be kept in mind that the purpose of price
cap regulation is to break the link between prices and operational
risks associated with things like acquisitions, corporate restructurings
and, of course, income trust conversions.
9749
Price cap regulation is designed to provide the regulated firm with
incentives that more closely approximate those of a competitive market structure
and to insulate customers from the risks associated with management‑initiated
changes such as acquisitions and corporate restructurings and the creation of
income trusts.
9750
So by way of conclusion, Mr. Chairman, what are we asking you do
to? Well, we are asking you to do
the following:
9751
To approve the competitive presence test and, with it, first, a rate
freeze in areas where the test is not passed.
9752
Second, relaxed regulation in areas where it is
passed.
9753
We are asking you to approve further rate
de‑averaging.
9754
We are asking you to approve a 5 percent rate element constraint for
PES and a 10 percent rate element constraint for business services, as is
currently in effect.
9755
We are asking you to approval removal of bundles from the cap and we are
asking you to uncap optional services.
9756
Mr. Chairman, these measures will achieve what TELUS believes is a key
objective for the next price cap regime, a matching of price cap regulation with
current competitive market conditions and the market conditions we expect will
evolve over the next four years.
9757
Thank you to you, Mr. Chairman, your fellow Commissioners and
Commission staff and the sundry other people who have made the hearing process
an efficient one. Thank you very
much for your attention this morning.
9758
Those are my submissions on de‑averaging.
9759
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you,
Mr. Ryan.
‑‑‑ Pause
9760
THE CHAIRPERSON: I think we
will have one more final argument before break, Madam
Secretary.
9761
THE SECRETARY: Thank you
very much, Mr. Chairman.
9762
I am now inviting counsel Engelhart on behalf of The Competitors to come
forward.
‑‑‑ Pause
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9763
MR. DUNBAR: Thank you. Thank you very much, Mr.
Chairman.
9764
It's Lawrence Dunbar and Ken Engelhart on behalf of The Competitors,
being for Canada's largest cable companies, Cogeco, Québecor Media through their
subsidiary Vidéotron, Rogers Communications Inc. and Shaw Communications
Inc.
9765
This price cap proceeding comes at a very interesting juncture in the
evolution of the Canadian telecommunications market. After almost a decade of laying the
groundwork for a competitive local exchange market, and after a major false
start with the first wave of CLECs, and after a considerable amount of
hand‑wringing, the industry is now showing some very positive signs of
competitive life.
9766
This more competitive environment if the product of the cable industries'
heavy investment in high‑speed broadband infrastructure, the Canadian public's
love affair with high‑speed Internet, and the development of IP
telephony.
9767
It is also, in no small measure, the result of the Commission's ongoing
efforts to foster the development of a competitive local exchange market through
its regulatory policies.
9768
The two previous price cap regimes might be characterized as trying to
replicate the impact of competitive market forces on the ILECs and to give them
a little more pricing flexibility.
9769
On the eve of the third price cap regime, we find ourselves further along
the continuum towards a competitive local market. Competitive market forces are clearly
gathering strength. They are not
yet reaching the threshold set by the Commission for regulatory
forbearance.
9770
It is quite possible that by the time the new regime takes effect in June
of next year that some local forbearance regions, or LFRs, will have satisfied
the tests for forbearance and the new regime will have little or no application
to them.
9771
Other LFRs will take longer to reach this stage and some, in more
remote areas, may never get there.
So the new price cap regime must be more adaptable than its
predecessors to diverse market conditions.
9772
Where competition is still weak or non‑existent, the Commission must have
regard to its statutory obligation to ensure that rates are just and reasonable,
and it must protect consumers from the ILEC's ability to raise prices to
unreasonable levels.
9773
At the other end of the spectrum where competition is strong and the
Commission's forbearance tests have been met within an LFR, we are of the view
that the Commission should let market forces replace
regulation.
9774
In between these two extremes is the inevitable grey area where
competitive market forces are clearly present and are gaining strength, but have
yet to reach levels that justify forbearance.
9775
The big question seems to be:
How much can we ease up on regulatory restraints without hurting the
interests of consumers?
9776
There has been considerable debate over the past year about the role of
competition in telecommunications in Canada, whether it is an objective in
itself or a means to an end, namely the improvement of consumer welfare. We believe that both are true. The ultimate goal of telecommunications
regulation is to improve the lot of consumers and business users, not
competitors.
9777
However, since competitive markets are generally considered to benefit
consumers to the greatest possible extent, it has become the role of regulators
to foster the development of competitive markets where monopolies were
previously the norm.
9778
It is therefore a mistake, in our view, to look at the existing
regulatory framework as a system designed to protect competitors as we have
sometimes heard it referred to in this proceeding. It is a system designed, at least in
part, to foster the development of a competitive marketplace that will hopefully
soon obviate the need for regulation and will ultimately maximize consumer
welfare.
9779
Looked at from this perspective, the question should not be whether this
or that particular restriction of the ILECs marketing and pricing activities
should be lifted now that the cable companies are truly engaged in the
market. But rather, whether the
relaxation of these restrictions, prior to forbearance and hence prior to the
ILECs' loss of market power, will jeopardize the maturation of the competitive
market and jeopardize ultimate forbearance.
9780
This is a public policy issue, not a competitive equity issue. The assumption in this proceeding seems
to be that now that the cable companies have made their investments in network
infrastructure and are attracting customers, the ILECs should be allowed to
fully take the gloves off and the cable companies should take their
lumps.
9781
There is a number of problems with this analysis. First, although the competitors have
successfully launched their IP‑based telephone services, all competitors,
including cable and non‑cable companies, still only have about 10 percent of the
market nationally. To our
knowledge, only one ILEC has met the Commission's thresholds for market share
loss in a single LFR, namely Aliant in the Halifax LFR.
9782
Furthermore, to our knowledge, no ILEC has yet satisfied the Commissions
Q of S requirements, quality of service requirements, for forbearance. Clearly therefore, whatever
liberalization takes place in this proceeding, it should not replicate the
degree of pricing flexibility accorded to the ILECs in forborne markets. This doesn't mean simply requiring
tariffs to be filed for approval.
The tariff filing mechanism will achieve nothing if it simply grants
approval to a wide range of discretionary prices. What you will end up with is a form of
forbearance under a different guise.
9783
Secondly, it is a mistake, in our view, to assume that the competitive
market will survive in a form that will best serve consumers' interests simply
because the cable companies will not abandon their sunk investment. While The Competitors have indicated
that they will not vacate the market if prices are driven down towards marginal
cost, this doesn't mean that they will necessarily make the new investments that
will be required in their networks in order that they can expand their customer
base and actively develop new products and services.
9784
As pointed out by Mr. Brazeau in his testimony, it is a fallacy to
think that the existing cable network is capable of carrying an infinite amount
of traffic, it clearly is not. If
the cable companies grow their subscriber base and provide the capacity
necessary to serve the ILECs' existing customer base, current investments will
have to be significantly augmented.
This will not occur in a predatory environment or an environment in which
targeted pricing responses denies competitors the opportunity to recover their
investment.
9785
Given this situation, the question is not whether greater pricing
flexibility prior to forbearance will drive the cable companies from the market,
but rather whether it will stall competitive entry at current levels, discourage
further investment and result in a mixed regime involving regulated
competition.
9786
We believe the Commission is on the right track, it has established
conditions for market entry that will enable a competitive market to develop and
it has established measurable thresholds for forbearance. Now is not the time to short‑circuit
this process by dramatically altering the rules of the game in advance of
forbearance.
9787
Now turning to our proposal, we believe that our proposal for the next
price regime best fits the dynamic market structure in which it will
operate. Our proposal will provide
the ILECs with increased pricing flexibility while continuing to protect
consumers from price increases associated with the ILECs' residual market
power.
9788
In our view, the so‑called one‑on‑one pricing proposed by the ILECs in
this proceeding falls only marginally short of a forbearance proposal. As Mr. Engelhart will discuss in a
few minutes, this degree of pricing flexibility is inappropriate in markets
where the ILECs still possess market power. It would enable them to target lower
pricing to customers who have decided to try a competitor's service while
maintaining higher prices in more inert markets.
9789
The Competitors' proposal takes a more balanced approach. In our view, it allows the ILECs a level
of pricing flexibility that is commensurate with emerging competition while
stopping short of allowing them to engage in individual pricing strategies to
recapture lost customers.
9790
There are several components to our proposal that will provide the ILECs
with greater flexibility to move prices both up and down. First, we are proposing that the ILECs
be permitted to engage in de‑averaging on a provincial basis at the commencement
of the new price cap regime. This
will enable both TELUS and Bell to address market differences that may exist
across provincial boundaries in the provinces they serve.
9791
Secondly, we are proposing to eliminate the X‑factor from the price cap
formula in respect of primary exchange services. This is fully consistent with the
Commission's approach to business local services in the second price cap
proceeding. At that time, the
Commission decided that the competitive market forces were sufficient to justify
the removal of the X‑factor, but not sufficient to justify forbearance. In our view, this is the situation that
now obtains in the non‑high‑class residential PES markets.
9792
The proposal to limit the X‑factor has been referred to on occasion in
this proceeding as a reform that is designed to permit prices to rise, but in
fact that is only half the equation.
Our proposal equally provides the ILECs with more room to pursue a
pricing strategy that involves price increases in some bands and price decreases
in others, provided that the other requirements of the price cap regime are
satisfied.
9793
The third component of our proposal is to restrict the overall price
increases in the residential and business local exchange markets to the rate of
inflation and to restrict individual price increases for specific rate elements
to 5 percent for residential and 10 percent for business. In our view, these measures will protect
consumers in more inert markets from unreasonable rate increases while providing
some additional pricing flexibility for the ILECs. In our view, this proposal lies
somewhere between the Consumers' proposal and the ILECs
proposal.
9794
The fourth element of Competitors' proposed reforms relates to price
de‑averaging. We are proposing that
the ILECs be granted additional pricing flexibility where there is cogent
evidence of increased competition within an LFR. When the ILECs have lost a 20 percent
market share in an LFR and the Q of S requirements have been satisfied, we are
proposing that the ILECs be permitted to engage in rate de‑averaging between
LFRs.
9795
In other words, we propose to allow prices in one LFR to differ from
prices in another while still requiring average prices within the more
competitive LFR. This would enable
ILECs to respond to increased competition in LFRs such as Calgary within a given
LFR while leaving prices untouched in other more inert markets. We believe that this approach is fully
consistent with the approach of the Commission in forbearance and its relaxation
of winback rules within LFRs where market share losses reached 20 percent and Q
of S standards have been satisfied.
9796
This approach is also superior to the ILECs' approach which looks at
competitive presence, but totally ignores market share loss in assessing
competitive intensity. Our approach
also differs from the ILECs insofar as it uses an LFR as a relevant geographic
area. Again, this is consistent
with the Commission's approach in the forbearance
decision.
9797
We believe that our approach involves a logical transition to full
forbearance and provides some initial price flexibility at the commencement of
the price cap period, it increases flexibility when market share losses of 20
percent are achieved and it allows for complete pricing flexibility following
forbearance where the ILECs have lost their market power.
9798
In our view, consumers will benefit at each stage of our proposal. At the outset, they will benefit from
some increases in ILEC prices, pricing flexibility, while being protected from
unreasonable price increases. In
exchanges where competitive forces are gathering strength consumers will benefit
from LFR‑based rate de‑averaging.
9799
Under our proposal, all consumers within a given LFR will benefit from
this type of rate de‑averaging since it will be applied on an LFR‑wide
basis.
9800
Finally, once an LFR is forborne, consumers can benefit from one to one
marketing if this is in fact what the ILECs want to provide. While there are inevitably tradeoffs to
be made with this type of transition from regulation to competitive market, we
believe that our proposal satisfies the need to protect consumers with a desire
to give greater weight to market forces when they gather sufficient strength to
be relied upon.
9801
MR. ENGELHART: The ILECs' proposals call for significantly greater
pricing flexibility at an earlier stage than our proposal. In fact, as disclosed by Mr. Bibic
during cross‑examination, what the ILECs really want is the ability to engage in
one‑on‑one marketing. Although it
is acknowledged to be impractical to do this on a company‑wide basis, that is
not what the ILECs have in mind.
What they have in mind is using this ultimate pricing flexibility as a
tool to retain vulnerable customers and to win back customers who have opted for
a competitor's service, this is the so‑called "save queue" referred to by
Mr. Collyer in his testimony.
9802
If granted this pricing flexibility prior to forbearance, the ILECs will
use it to retain or recapture valuable customers while continuing to charge more
inert customers higher rates. The
ILECs claim that this form of Ramsay pricing is normal in competitive
markets. In fact, it is not the
norm in fully competitive markets or workably competitive markets since in such
markets there are no inert customers and higher prices cannot be sustained. Ramsay pricing is the pricing strategy
of choice for firms with market power.
9803
It is the presence of significant market power that enables price
increases to be made, not the presence of competitive market forces. It is precisely because of the ILECs'
ability to engage in selective price discrimination that regulatory safeguards
continue to be required prior to forbearance. It is also because of this dominant
position as former monopoly suppliers of PES that the ILECs know which customers
are most valuable to retain or recapture and what their specific
telecommunications requirements are and when they leave. This puts the ILECs in a unique position
to target these customers and address their individual
needs.
9804
This was borne out by Bell Canada's own expert witness in the local
forbearance proceeding last year.
According to Dr. McFetridge, perfect price discrimination requires that
the seller charge each buyer the maximum amount that each buyer is willing to
pay, known as the buyer's marginal evaluation, for each successive unit of the
product purchased.
9805
This requires that the seller know the demand characteristics of each
buyer and deal with each buyer separately.
This is highly unlikely in practice, because this type of information is
almost never available to the seller.
It is, however, largely available to former monopolies in network
businesses such as this because of their unique knowledge of the customer base
and it enables the ILECs to engage in this selective form of price
discrimination in a surgical manner.
9806
If there is any question as to who benefits from Ramsay pricing in these
circumstances, Dr. McFetridge provided the answer in very succinct terms. If there is perfect competition among
sellers, the entire surplus gained from exchange accrues to customers. If there is perfect price
discrimination, the entire surplus gained from exchange accrues to the
seller.
9807
We are not alone in our criticism of rate de‑averaging prior to
forbearance. As recently as last
year the Commission stated that allowing the ILECs to respond to market forces
within a geographic area of a rate band through rate de‑averaging would allow
for a degree of targeted pricing which could subject other customers in the rate
band to an undue discrimination, result in rates that are not just and
reasonable and slow the development of fair and sustainable
competition.
9808
In these circumstances, one might wonder how the ILECs can justify their
Ramsay pricing approach as being in the public interest. Bell Canada offers three principal
arguments. First, they say this is
business as usual in competitive markets.
Everyone does it so why can't we?
As I mentioned in my cross‑examination of the Bell panel, this puts me in
mind of my children saying that all their friends have a TV in their bedrooms or
everyone else gets to stay out until 2:00 a.m.
9809
Upon examination, this type of proposition usually ends up being
untrue. There may be one kid with a
TV in his or her room or one kid that gets to stay out all night, but it is not
the norm. The same is true of the
type of rate de‑averaging sought by the ILECs in this
proceeding.
9810
You will recall that during cross‑examination of Bell's panel I asked
them to give examples of rate de‑averaging that Bell engages in in the
long‑distance high‑speed Internet and broadcasting distribution markets, all
competitive markets in which their retail pricing activity is not
regulated. The panel was
hard‑pressed to come up with any examples other than a $2.00 price differential
on Sympatico service in Quebec.
9811
It was not until after the lunch break on Tuesday following what I assume
was a wild flurry of activity that the panel was able to come up with a few more
examples of what they said were price de‑averaging in those markets. All of these examples were unadvertised
and unpublished save offers. This
hardly amounts to evidence of any widespread practice.
9812
The truth is that, with one or two exceptions and some provincial
differences, the communications industry in Canada generally does not engage in
widespread price de‑averaging. It
is a practice that pays the greatest dividends for companies that face
competition in some sectors and enjoy monopoly power in others. It allows the perpetrator to fleece the
inert segments and marginalize competitors where they surface. It is not the competitive norm and it is
not in the public interest.
9813
The second justification advanced by Bell for rate de‑averaging is that
in a market characterized by high‑fixed and common costs differential pricing is
necessary in order to stay financially viable. If Bell were correct in its assertion,
one would expect to find numerous examples in the long‑distance BDU and
high‑speed Internet markets.
However, the record of this proceeding defies Bell's proposition. Geographic de‑averaging is the exception
rather than the rule.
9814
If one really wants to understand the rationale for Bell's proposal, one
needs to insert the words "monopoly profit" into the equation. What Bell wants is the ability to exact
a monopoly profit from inert customers and customers who do not yet have
competitive alternatives while protecting its customer base in other regions
where competition is emerging.
9815
The reason why we don't see this pricing strategy in competitive markets
is because such markets are generally not characterized by suppliers with market
power and inert customers. As far
as financial viability is concerned it is difficult to see how Bell's financial
viability is anymore at stake than its competitors who also have high‑fixed and
common costs, but who lack inert markets from which to recover
them.
9816
The big danger, if Bell is granted the flexibility it seeks, is that Bell
will drive prices down to cost in a selective manner, thereby denying its
competitors the ability to expand their operations.
9817
The third reason advanced by the ILECs in favour of eliminating the
restriction on rate de‑averaging is that the current rule encourage uneconomic
entry insofar as it provides a price umbrella effectively protecting new
entrants even where they are inefficient.
Again, this proposition does not hold up to
scrutiny.
9818
The cable companies have not invested hundreds of millions of dollars to
enter a market on an uneconomic basis knowing that rates will be forborne in
most major markets over the next year or so. Who are the uneconomic entrants? The ILECs have failed to identify
them. As acknowledged by
Mr. Hariton, it is also a fallacy to suggest that competitors are facing a
single averaged price in the regions in which they
compete.
9819
The ILECs themselves already have numerous rate bands and sub‑bands
within their respective operating territory. If The Competitors' proposal for
provincial de‑averaging is accepted, this number of different bands will double
in Bell Canada's territory.
Moreover, these rate bands already embody cost differentials inherent in
providing services.
9820
Some companies like Vidéotron already face competition from three
different ILECs in their operating territory. This obviously multiplies the number of
different rates they already face.
There are also other competitors in the market such as Primus and Vonage
who again have different rates.
Which of these many rates provides the umbrella for a new
entrant?
9821
If what Bell suggests were true, one would expect the cable companies to
have at least one rate plan for each ILEC rate band they compete in, but this is
not the case. While The
Competitors' price plans and service bundles may differ, they generally do not
segment their pricing on a customer‑specific or narrow geographic basis in the
way that the ILECs say they want to.
9822
TELUS complaint about rate averaging is a little different than
Bell's. TELUS is worried that
competitors will target customers within an exchange that have short loops since
these customers are less expensive to serve. TELUS fears that its obligation to
provide service to urban ranchers with long loops increases its marginal costs
and enables competitors to engage in cherry picking. Again, this is not borne out by the
facts.
9823
As testified to by The Competitors' panel on Friday, the cable companies
are entering the telephony market on a network‑wide basis wherever they have
upgraded facilities. They are not
picking and choosing their locations based on the ILECs' loop lengths. Indeed, the cable companies do not use
loops that run from the customers' premises to a central office, they use drops
which run from the cable distribution network to the customers' premises and
they are offering their services to anyone who is served by their
network.
9824
Since over 95 percent of homes in Canada are passed by cable networks and
approximately 88 percent of them can be served by high‑speed Internet, there
really is no reason at all to think that a cherry‑picking strategy is being
pursued.
9825
Other competitors like Vonage and Primus do not use loops either. They either run their VoIP service over
the ILECs and cable companies' high‑speed Internet services or resell ILECs'
local loops. It is difficult to
identify any major new entrant who is cherry picking in the manner suggested by
TELUS.
9826
As pointed out by Commissioner Langford during the proceeding, the
company's own evidence contradicts the notion that the ILECs' longer loops are a
burden to them. According to the
companies, once the network is in place the marginal cost of providing services
to premises passed by its network is negligible. Since the ILECs have already constructed
their networks and their marginal costs are negligible, it is difficult to see
why they feel the need to raise prices to these customers with the long
loops.
9827
TELUS marketing panel also made the point that it is difficult to market
its local services to a marketing region like Calgary that has a number of
different rate bands. The
Competitors have some sympathy with this problem. It is for this reason that we are
proposing to permit an ILEC to adopt a new LFR‑specific rate whenever that ILEC
has lost 20 percent of its market share in a given LFR. By allowing new LFR‑specific rates when
competitive market forces have established a firm foothold, it will be possible
for TELUS and the other ILECs to simplify their marketing efforts within the
Calgary or other LFRs.
9828
Such relief is not far away.
We expect that a number of major LFRs will reach the 20 percent threshold
in 2007, possibly prior to the commencement of the third price cap
period.
9829
We also believe that the ILECs have more pricing options available to
them under the existing rules than they have acknowledged in their
evidence. The shackles of
regulation are not nearly as constraining as the ILECs would have you
believe. During their
cross‑examination of The Competitors' panel of witnesses the ILECs' counsel
identified numerous bundles of services offered by the cable
companies.
9830
But as pointed out by Mr. Watt, the ILECs are quite capable of
providing bundles themselves. Why
they don't do more bundling is a mystery to the cable industry. Although the ILECs are required to cost
local service at the tariff rate, they can cost other unregulated items in their
bundles such as high‑speed Internet, long‑distance service or BDU services at
acquisition costs which is a modest threshold indeed.
9831
Counsel for The Companies also pointed to both purchase deals for
multi‑tenant buildings that Rogers engages in in its cable TV business. Again, the ILECs can already do
this. There are numerous examples
of tariffs that contain volume discounts that have been approved by the
Commission. This has nothing to do
with rate de‑averaging.
9832
Counsel for The Companies also introduced The Companies' Exhibit No. 10
to The Competitors' panel, which was the offer to new housing owners of
three‑year service for Rogers cable TV, telephone and high‑speed Internet
service. As explained by
Mr. Watt, this was a deal purchased by the real estate developer to assist
with its house sales. Mr. Watt
also pointed out that Aliant had made a similar deal available to developers in
its operating territory.
9833
Why other ILECs don't do this, we don't know. The answer is not to do away with rate
de‑averaging. Indeed, the record
shows that the ILECs could be doing more innovative marketing than they are
currently doing under the existing rules.
9834
For all of these reasons, we believe that our proposal best meets the
policy objectives of a price cap plan at this juncture in the development of the
competitive local telephone market.
9835
Thank you very much.
9836
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you, Messrs. Dunbar and
Engelhart.
9837
We will take a break and begin again at five minutes to
11:00.
‑‑‑ Upon recessing at 1035 / Suspension à
1035
‑‑‑ Upon resuming at 1055 / Reprise à
1055
9838
THE CHAIRMAN: Order, please. À l'ordre, s'il vous
plaît.
9839
Madame la secrétaire.
9840
LA SECRÉTAIRE: Merci,
monsieur le président.
9841
I would like to invite now counsel Janigan and Lawford on behalf of
Consumer Groups to proceed with their final argument.
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9842
MR. JANIGAN: Thank you, Mr.
Chair, and members of the hearing panel for the opportunity to address you today
and to give the substance of the argument of the Consumer Groups that we'll be
advancing in written form next week.
9843
My colleague, Mr. Lawford, and I intend to proceed in a tag‑team fashion
and that will hopefully terminate somewhat less histrionically than the
wrestling variety.
9844
We apologize that we are unable to touch upon all the items under
consideration implicitly or explicitly raised by the Public Notice, but
hopefully we may be able to address them in our argument next
week.
9845
The Commission has flagged objectives of the regime as initial item to be
addressed. With the benefit of
hindsight, the Consumer Groups question the utility of the concept of
objectives, particularly in relation to statutory test tasks before the
Commission.
9846
With respect, the Consumer Groups believe that the introduction of a set
of values on top of the Commission's clear responsibilities to set rates based
upon a standard of just and reasonable has not generally been helpful,
particularly for the consumer interest in the rate‑making
process.
9847
Many participants in this proceeding have quoted from the
Telecommunications Policy Review Panel Report, a comprehensive document that
advances an agenda of change and reform, both in terms of reducing regulatory
oversight in some areas and enhancing them in others.
9848
Whatever the view concerning its recommendations, care must be taken in
the context of this proceeding to parcel those elements that require statutory
change that has not yet occurred.
9849
In particular, in this proceeding, rates must be fashioned in a way that
engages the balancing of the rate payer and regulated company interest, namely
the right to earn a return that fairly compensates the company and recovers its
investment and, at the same time, provides service at the most efficient rate
for the rate payer.
9850
This principle did not go selling out the door when price caps were
adopted. Price caps were adopted as
the best way to meet this objective principally through the control of prices
and an allocation of a share of estimated productivity benefits as well as
provision of incentives to the regulated company.
9851
Since Decision 9419, the price cap company has financial incentives for
efficient allocation of costs and introduction of productivity enhancement. I should say since the principles
advanced by Decision 9419.
9852
There is a diminution of the opportunities to cross‑subsidize products
and services of the basket structure and reduction of regulatory scrutiny
between performance reviews.
9853
All of this comes with the implementation of a price cap. Thus, a price cap is thought by many to
be the superior instrument for regulation ‑‑
1100 ‑‑ of incumbent monopoly services in
markets where there is a merging competition in that it better prepares the
incumbent for competition or protecting rate payer
interest.
9854
While the specified terms of the price cap formula and its application
involve the application of judgment, they are not so elastic as to enable some
kind of re‑configuration to meet other policy objectives, particularly those
that conflict with the Commission's duty to set just and reasonable
rates.
9855
The Consumer Groups don't object to the restatement of the accepted
objectives of the price cap regulation.
We just believe that the experience of the last price cap is a cautionary
tail involving the perils of using the price cap rate‑making tool as a fixer of
all perceived problems in telecommunications markets.
9856
The record is a replete with the complaints of the effects of the
existing regulatory regime on the interest of particular
stakeholders.
9857
We will address a little later some of these complaints that deal with
the necessity to maintain particularly regulatory constraints as part of the
price cap framework, but we would first speak to the aspect of redress of
structural or financial inequities that seems to flow through elements of the
record of this proceeding put forth by some key industry
stakeholders.
9858
We believe that any balancing exercise associated with the rate‑making
process must consider what residential rate payers have already paid to attempt
to facilitate the development of competitive markets.
9859
And when we see this, we realize it's far too late in the day to roll
back the clock, but it's important to remember where we have
been.
9860
We embarked upon the restructure in the telecom markets in a major way in
the proceedings that gave rise to Commission Decision 9278 allowing competition
interconnection on the toll market.
9861
With the advent of competition and the cost pressures inefficiencies that
would be so enabled, the Commission, at that time, in a sunny fashion, deflected
the inevitability of local rate increases.
They came later in a three‑year sequence.
9862
By the middle of the decade, the incredible productivity enhancement
associated with digital technology and the digitization of incumbent networks
paid for by years of rates and service improvement plans were to finally deliver
on their promise.
9863
At this juncture, by a remarkable coincidence, we migrated the separation
of the company and the competitive and utility elements and subsequently, the
price regulation rather than cost of service.
9864
Did we fairly share the productivity associated with the technological
developments in subsequent regulation?
We will return to that point.
9865
Later, in the first price cap period, the basket structure so designed
facilitated the flowing of price reductions exclusively to business customers to
bitterest the high like defence against competitive entry.
9866
Residential rates payers also funded local numbered portability costs and
other costs of local competition.
9867
Through the application of Decision 2002‑34 almost one billion and a half
dollars from rate reductions were never passed on to residential local consumers
to make sure the competitors had a price that they could
beat.
9868
Much of this money flowed out to pay for price discounts, for access
digital networks to Competitors who still, by and large, only serve the business
market.
9869
The customer benefits were modest in comparison. By mid‑2002, ten years after Decision
9278, customer price changes were slightly less than inflation for the decade
before with higher telephone bills being paid by the typical residential
customer.
9870
This is hardly an impressive record for an industry that showed five
times the long run economy‑wide TFP growth in the same period of
time.
9871
Residential customers are tired of being the shock absorbers for every
bump on the road to competition paradise.
There are seemingly no limit to the willingness of other stakeholders to
volunteer us for financial burdens and risk in order to make the market work for
them.
9872
Unless they be deterred from awarding their shareholders by the
courageous pursuit of every productivity enhancement or the cost cutting measure
available, we will also not be peeking behind the corporate veil to judge
winners and losers from the last price cap period.
9873
Thus, we have in this proceeding not only the heads scratching task of
constructing a price cap from the assortment of an imperfectly max. statistical
instruments and assumptions attributable to the difficulty of matching inputs
and outputs in the corporate structures, even if the data could be
produced.
9874
Residential primary exchange service seems to have wholly grail
proportions from a marketing standpoint what is a seeming back allay for
productivity, destined to be another service riding on the ILEC network as Bell
Canada's Mr. Hariton has noted.
9875
My colleague, Mr. Lawford, will describe the model that commands itself
to the Consumer Groups based on the record, but I wish to direct some comments
after Mr. Lawford is finished on the subject of various uncapping and
de‑averaging proposals that have been ventilated by Bell and TELUS in this
proceeding.
9876
Actually, I wish to do this now and I'll have some comments after Mr.
Lawford's finishing edition.
9877
With respect to the uncapping and de‑averaging proposals, we would submit
that the net effect of these proposals is to reargue the appropriate tests for
forbearance. This time, the bar is
to be set lower to enable more pricing flexibility.
9878
In the case of the uncapping tests, the Commission Decision 2006‑15 would
suggest that the ILEC would be left with residual market power. Market power means the ability to raise
prices profitably above competitive levels.
9879
Rate decreases spurred by rate de‑averaging can create head room under
the cap that needs rive rate increases for customers residing in non competitive
areas that depend upon regulatory protection.
9880
Finally, the proposal struck away the practical of the benefit of the
price ceiling for local PES that was established in Decision
2006‑15.
9881
From what we can gather, the insurance against the ILECS exercising
market power or their ability to increase rate is yet another blue sky view of
the market, something to the effect that this time we are really really really
certain that competition will protect you.
9882
What the proposals actually say is that customers should once again
provide the shock absorber, this time the insulation against the incumbents
losing too much market share.
9883
If the market is competitive and market power cannot be exercised to the
detriment of customers, then forebear regulation. Let's not have pretence structures that
are for the benefit of the incumbent only.
We have already paid billions for competition. We can wait till it actually arrives
without once again compensating the incumbents.
9884
Mr. Lawford will now discuss the model that we have proposed, as I've
indicated.
9885
MR. LAWFORD: Good
morning. The Consumer Groups have
proposed retaining the present basket structure for a further period of four
years which, we submit, is a reasonable position, given the emphasis of the
companies and TELUS upon what is, in our submission, an effective avoidance of
the price cap and in an round around the Commission's forbearance
framework.
9886
The Commission has not, in our submission, received compelling evidence
that would indicate competition is sufficient to prevent the exercise of ILEC
market power in the areas where the companies or TELUS uncapping tests would be
met. The actual evidence of
substitute ability is also spody.
Cable telephony is offered as part
of higher price bundles in markets where competition could be expected for PES
under the present price capping ‑‑ pardon me.
9887
Cable telephony is offered as part of higher price bundles in markets
where competition could be expected under the present price cap if indeed there
are room for an economic entry.
Instead basic service, customer simply face a competitive choice with
cable telephony that is no choice at all.
9888
Cable operators either are not offering equivalent of a stand‑alone PES,
instead offering bundles with optional features or with forborne services or pricing their
stand‑alone PES at prices which are well above ILEC primary exchange service
rates under the present rate cap.
9889
Retaining a price cap would enable a more coherent transition to
forbearance than allowing ILEC dominance to be cemented in areas where the
potential for competition from cable and VoIP is only just beginning to take
hold.
9890
The Consumers' proposed price cap index calculation is the only one that
fairly attempts to reflect the reality of network growth and economies of scale
in the last price cap period.
9891
While the assumptions have baseline productivity used in this analysis
may be questioned as to their exactitude, it is notable that the unavailability
of more recent figures is a consequence of the ILECS own insistence on avoiding
reporting any costs or revenues, even for the purpose of designing an
appropriate rate cap.
9892
In such circumstances, it is entirely reasonable for the Consumer Groups
to propose an X factor based on the latest hard figures for a total factor
productivity.
9893
Total factor productivity calculation driving X factor is a key issue in
this proceeding. The Consumer
Groups are well aware that the Commission has moved away from TFP
calculation. However, we are
requesting a consideration of likely ILEC TFP precisely because it is the
fairest theoretical measure of the reality of ILEC
outputs.
9894
Scope economies, outputs and therefore productivity enjoyed by the ILECs
since the last price cap decision will be implicitly assigned under the ILECs
proposals to unregulated services such as DSL and wireless while primary
exchange service subscribers are saddled with nominal inputs for these services,
resulting in higher primary exchange service prices.
9895
The Consumer Groups price index is also the only one that attempts to
fully reflect the totality of inputs.
9896
We include a calculation of input price differential which we feel
accurately reflects the real performance of ILECs relative to the general
economy.
9897
As for outputs, we also include an explicit stretch factor to account for
rising industry productivity levels due to economies of scope from such newer
services as DSL, gaming and ring tones.
9898
This stretch factor is an attempt to fairly proportion some of the scope
productivity benefits to the consumer side of the ledger in the Commission's
attempt to set just and reasonable rates.
9899
Again this is a mechanism to avoid the situation where ILECs attribute
100 percent of productivity gains to forborne services and 100 percent of the
joint and common cost to residential PES, which unjustly raises rates for
consumers and provides supernormal profits to shareholders in areas where ILECs
have significant market power.
9900
ILEC productivity estimates produces at the prodding of the Commission in
this proceeding lack the air of reality required to avoid the risk that
consumers will gain nothing from the likely positive industry performance during
the next price cap period.
9901
As a belt that we add to the suspenders of the price cap formula, the
Consumer Groups have further called for any rate increases under the cap for
residential services basket to be limited to the lesser of GDP, PI inflation or
five percent.
9902
I would like to say a word about high‑cost service areas. The Consumer Groups strongly support the
continuation of a separate high‑cost service areas
sub‑basket.
9903
High‑cost service areas are under‑served and unserved areas where
affordability of telephone service is a major issue for many
residents.
9904
Proposals to eliminate the high‑cost service area basket by combining
with other non‑high‑cost service area baskets in a single residential services
basket as supported by some of the ILECs raises a host of potential problems for
these sensitive areas which are well outside the scope of the
proceeding.
9905
We urge the Commission to consider these proposals to remove high‑cost
service area baskets with much caution.
9906
We are turning now to the basket structure. The Consumer Groups are very concerned
with the Commission's treatment of optional services such as caller ID or
voicemail.
9907
Optional services, a highly lucrative segment of ILEC utility operations
during the reporting period, were not capped under the first price cap, and
consumers experienced significant increase.
9908
The present optional services price cap of a dollar per year is a rather
casual limitation, and not reflective of other rate caps in other
baskets.
9909
These are services that cannot be obtained on a stand‑alone basis. Leaving the option of doing without is
the only choice in areas without meaningful competition.
9910
In the Consumer Groups view, the Commission has had enough fights on
their match card already to open another one with Canadian consumers about
whether optional services are really important to them.
9911
We think that they are. In our survey, which is contained in our response
to CAC/MSOS number 6, we feel that there is a contention that the Commission
shouldn't be blasé about the exercise of market power in these
services.
9912
We therefore propose a more rational optional services price cap of GDPPI
plus three percent.
9913
Michael?
‑‑‑ Pause
9914
I am just going to address one more area: pay phones. Pay phones is a subject
close to our heart.
9915
Only the companies have proposed an increase in pay phone rates. In fact,
a one hundred percent increase from 25 cents to 50 cents per call, while the
other parties have seen fit at most to call on the Commission to consider rates
on a case‑by‑case basis.
9916
What is most intriguing to the Consumer Groups is the company's
willingness to engage the proceeding about the financial performance of an
underperforming service such as pay phones ‑‑ which according to their
statement 60 percent of pay phones are losers and only 40 percent
winners ‑‑ but clearly not in their other lines of
business.
9917
From this we feel it is fair to infer that the other product areas,
including primary exchange service, are doing quite well.
9918
It is far too late in the day to contemplate cherry‑picked price changes
in the cap structure in turn driven by notional concepts of appropriate
financial results.
9919
We don't have a public service regime for pay phones, and doubling rates
without even a cursory analysis of the impact on access would be potentially
reckless to customer interests.
9920
The Consumer Groups call upon the Commission, to whom these costs and
revenues have been provided, to refuse the company's request of doubling pay
phone rates as unnecessary and excessive.
9921
MR. JANIGAN: Thank
you.
9922
The final section of our oral argument deals with what I have termed
policy options, and we have set out in this argument a price cap model that we
believe fairly advances the interest of customers who, as I indicated, are still
waiting for delivery of promises of a half‑generation ago.
9923
However, there are other potentially practical options perhaps less
commendable than those that we have advanced before the Commission that perhaps
the Commission might wish to consider.
9924
Now the companies and TELUS say that their proposals are not about
increasing rates. And I know it is
received wisdom that when someone tells that it is not about the money it
usually is about the money.
9925
Let us take them at their word for the purpose of considering this
option. The ILECs, as a general proposition, don't wish to increase rates on
average.
9926
Their proposals, on the other hand, torture the very principles of price
cap regulation, particularly simplicity to produce the desired result with large
gaps in consumer price protection.
9927
Perhaps in incorporating some elements of the proposals from the ILECs
the Commission may wish to consider a cap which simply provides that rates for
regulated services will not increase during the price cap
period.
9928
This means that the ILECs may decrease rates whenever, whatever rates
they wish, provided the imputation test is met and the rates are not
discriminatory within the meaning of the Act.
9929
We take no position on matters such as win‑back or promotion rules. We assume they are going to remain in
effect.
9930
We would then have no average price index, no baskets, no de‑averaging
rule or competitive presence tests.
Rates simply won't be increased.
9931
When the Commission forbearance test is met the service is forborne in
the forbearance area subject to customer protections provided in the
decision.
9932
This option preserves the logical framework of deregulation and
transition that has been commenced by the Commission and puts an end to ILEC
whining about the regulatory straightjacket.
9933
It is administratively simple and provides some real protection to
customers in non‑competitive areas.
9934
There is also some rough justice about this option.
9935
If the industry fuss is really about barriers to price competition, then
go ahead and let them compete. If
it is about raising rates driven by market power, Ramsay pricing or some other
cozy one‑sided concept to benefit shareholders, then the door should be firmly
shut.
9936
Consumer Groups are pleased to have had the opportunity to make these
submissions to the Commission. We
look forward to amplifying them in our written argument. We hope our submissions will be of
assistance to you in the deliberation.
And we extend our thanks to the hearing panel, to you, Mr. Chairman, to
the Commission and Commission staff, and our fellow parties for the cooperation
throughout this proceeding.
9937
THE CHAIRMAN: Thank you, Mr.
Janigan. Thank you, Mr.
Lawford.
‑‑‑ Pause
9938
LA SECRÉTAIRE : Merci.
9939
Nous allons maintenant procéder avec le plaidoyer final de monsieur Dany
Provençal au nom de l'Union des consommateurs.
9940
LE PRÉSIDENT : Me Provençal, bienvenue.
‑‑‑ Pause
9941
M. PROVENÇAL : Malheureusement, je ne suis pas un maître. Je suis le
représentant...
9942
LE PRÉSIDENT : C'est bien. On va procéder quand
même.
‑‑‑ Rires / Laughter
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
9943
M. PROVENÇAL : Merci beaucoup.
9944
Alors, Monsieur le Président, Conseiller et Conseillères, mon nom est
Dany Provençal. Je suis économiste en politiques et réglementation à l'Union des
consommateurs.
9945
J'aimerais tout d'abord remercier le Conseil ainsi que l'ensemble des
intervenants impliqués dans cet audience suite à l'avis public Télécom CRTC
2006‑05.
9946
Notre argumentation sera brève et concernera les principaux éléments
jugés pertinents pour la prise en compte des intérêts des consommateurs de
services téléphoniques résidentiels.
9947
Les sujets en question seront dans l'ordre des éléments du cadre de
l'audience : le test de présence de concurrence, la formule de plafonnement des
prix, la composition des paniers de service, la subdivision des tarifs, et nous
allons terminer par de brefs commentaires en guise de
conclusion.
9948
Alors, tout d'abord, les éléments concernant les revenus et bénéfices des
ESLT n'ont pas été retenus à l'intérieur du cadre de la présente
audience.
9949
Nous croyons cependant que les données sur les revenus et bénéfices
peuvent permettre d'apprécier le niveau de productivité atteint par les
entreprises et de le comparer avec l'évolution des tarifs.
9950
Nous aimerions également souligner le fait que les compagnies (donc,
TELUS Canada, Bell Alliant et Sask Tel), TELUS et les concurrents ont également
soulevé des informations de nature financière, que ce soit dans leurs preuves,
durant les contre‑interrogatoires ou même comme pièces
justificatives.
9951
Nous trouverions donc injuste que les compagnies puissent présenter et
échanger ces types d'information pour ensuite les utiliser dans leurs
argumentations, alors que les groupes de consommateurs ne peuvent pas s'y
référer et ainsi juger du caractère juste et raisonnable des tarifs des services
résidentiels. Toutefois, nous respectons et acceptons les consignes du Conseil à
cet égard.
9952
En ce qui concerne les tests proposés par les compagnies et par TELUS
pour déterminer le degré de concurrence dans un marché donné, l'Union des
consommateurs croit que ces tests ne permettent pas de protéger adéquatement le
consommateurs résidentiels de l'exercice d'un pouvoir de marché par les
ESLT.
9953
La présence d'une seule alternative n'est pas suffisante pour générer les
effets bénéfiques potentiels d'un marché en concurrence.
9954
Les possibilités de développement d'un duopole formé par une ESLT et une
compagnie de câblodistribution sont réelles, et cette structure de marché n'est
pas souhaitable du point de vue du consommateur.
9955
Ensuite, selon les compagnies, l'éviction d'un concurrent utilisant les
installations de service locales existantes par une ESLT permettrait tout de
même à un autre concurrent de tenter sa chance dans le
marché.
9956
On peut se demander quelle entreprise pourrait bien vouloir se placer
dans une telle position de vulnérabilité face à une ESLT qui a déjà évincé un
concurrent.
9957
On peut se demander également :
9958
Pour quelle raison les ESLT veulent‑elles absolument voir le plafond
tarifaire retiré ?
9959
En quoi l'augmentation des tarifs serait‑elle une réponse à l'émergence
de la concurrence ?
9960
Et plutôt que de retirer le plafond pour le réintroduire après l'éviction
de la concurrence, pourquoi ne pas la conserver et ainsi éviter des délais et
des coûts de réglementation ?
9961
Si les forces du marché sont aussi fiables et leurs résultats si
intéressants et presque certains que le prétendent les ESLT, pourquoi celles‑ci
doutent‑elles de leur capacité à réduire les prix au bénéfice des consommateurs
en voulant retirer le plafond ? Qu'est‑ce qui justifie de conserver la
possibilité d'augmenter les tarifs si toutes les raisons pour ne pas s'en servir
sont là ?
9962
La question se pose.
9963
Le souci des ESLT pour les entrants potentiels est sans doute louable,
mais nous ne devons pas mettre de côté les intérêts des titulaires, soit la
possibilité d'affronter la concurrence et de maximiser les profits en maintenant
un facteur X qui ne décourage pas l'entrée de concurrents.
‑‑‑ Pause
9964
Voilà qui nous amène donc à la formule de plafonnement des
prix.
9965
L'établissement d'un facteur X qui reflète le plus fidèlement possible
les gains de productivité dans l'industrie représente l'élément primordial d'un
régime de plafonnement des prix.
9966
La protection des entrants ne doit pas servir de prétexte à
l'établissement d'un facteur X plus faible que la productivité qui est
effectivement observée dans l'industrie.
9967
Les consommateurs résidentiels ne devraient pas avoir à payer davantage
pour protéger les concurrents ou favoriser l'émergence de la
concurrence.
9968
Si la concurrence est effectivement inévitable, celle‑ci devrait être en
mesure d'entrer selon le véritable état de la productivité dans le marché,
incluant les gains générés par le service DSL ou LAM.
9969
Il serait donc préférable d'appliquer un facteur X qui permette de
refléter le plus fidèlement possible les caractéristiques qui soient
technologiques, structurelles ou historiques du secteur et d'éviter l'entrée
inefficace de concurrents.
9970
L'argumentation des compagnies et de TELUS porte à croire que celles‑ci
se préoccupent du sort des concurrents actuels et potentiels. En effet, ces ESLT
ont mentionné que l'établissement d'un facteur X trop élevé pouvait nuire à
l'émergence de la concurrence.
9971
Pourtant, ces ESLT ont également démontré une forte préoccupation
relative à l'évolution foudroyante de la concurrence.
9972
Ces deux positionnements semblent quelque peu contradictoires, car d'une
part ces ESLT invoquent la protection des entrants pour justifier une
application conservatrice du facteur X, alors que d'autre part elles soutiennent
que l'émergence de la concurrence semble inévitable et
menaçante.
9973
Donc, pour éviter d'être sujettes à une formule de plafonnement des prix
qui incite davantage à la performance, les compagnies et TELUS sont prêtes à
soulever des arguments en faveur d'un soutien à l'entrée des
concurrents.
9974
Par contre, toujours selon elles, ces mêmes concurrents constituent une
menace imminente et menaçante.
9975
Juste avant de terminer ce point d'argumentation, nous jugeons utile de
mentionner que la conversion de TELUS et de Bell en fiducies de revenus devrait
être prise en compte.
9976
Les économies d'impôt ainsi réalisées risquent de permettre à ces deux
compagnies d'être encore plus rentables, notamment grâce à la contribution de
leur clientèle résidentielle stable et même captive par
endroits.
9977
Si la structure du secteur des services téléphoniques locaux constitue un
important facteur permettant à ces entreprises de se convertir en fiducies de
revenus, pourquoi ne pas en tenir compte dans la détermination de la
productivité dans l'ensemble de l'industrie ?
9978
Pour ce qui est de la composition des paniers de service, nous tenons
seulement à mentionner que les services optionnels résidentiels devraient être
considérés au même titre que les services résidentiels de base, ou du moins
certains.
9979
En effet, l'impossibilité pour un client résidentiel de se procurer les
services optionnels par un fournisseur autre que le détenteur de la ligne de
services de base constitue un obstacle au choix du
consommateur.
9980
La question des offres regroupées, ou des * bundles +, semble également poser
problème.
9981
Dans le cas d'un client qui bénéficie du service de * Res PES + plafonné et du service d'afficheur,
par exemple, qui n'est pas plafonné, le fait de se procurer ces deux services à
l'intérieur d'une même offre de services aurait pour résultat d'éliminer le
plafond pour les deux services composant l'offre
regroupée.
9982
Dans un tel cas, le client devra de lui‑même s'assurer que le prix du
forfait ne dépasse pas le prix des deux services pris
individuellement.
9983
A notre avis, les ESLT devraient accepter une plus grande part de
responsabilité dans l'application des modalités qui visent à donner une plus
grande flexibilité. Pour elles, en fait.
9984
Comme dernier point, l'Union des consommateurs est préoccupée par les
propositions de subdivision des tarifs des compagnies et de
TELUS.
9985
En effet, la subdivision des tarifs à l'intérieur d'une même catégorie
tarifaire pourrait permettre à une ESLT de réduire les tarifs dans les régions
où la concurrence est présente et d'augmenter les tarifs dans les autres
régions, où la concurrence n'est pas présente.
9986
Ces dispositions permettraient donc aux ESLT d'affronter plus
efficacement la concurrence où elle se présente, tout en faisant absorber les
pertes de revenu liées aux réductions de tarifs par les consommateurs des
régions où la concurrence n'est pas présente.
9987
Ces consommateurs ne bénéficieraient pas nécessairement du régime de
plafonnement des prix et pourraient même être désavantagés par les dispositions
proposées.
9988
En guise de conclusion, l'Union des consommateurs tient à formuler
certains commentaires généraux.
9989
D'abord, nous ne devons pas perdre de vue l'objectif de maximisation des
profits qu'ont les entreprises, notamment celles sujettes à la réglementation de
monopoles.
9990
Cela se traduit par une volonté pour elles d'augmenter ou d'éviter de
réduire les tarifs malgré des gains de productivité importants, tout en voulant
se donner une marge de manoeuvre pour affronter et écarter la
concurrence.
9991
Ensuite, nous croyons que les ESLT ont encore un pouvoir de marché
considérable, spécialement dans le secteur résidentiel, et un positionnement
avantageux en termes d'infrastructure.
9992
Les ESLT auraient tout avantage à précipiter l'entrée de concurrents tout
en réduisant autant que possible les contraintes réglementaires de façon à les
devancer et ainsi contenir ou même freiner l'émergence de la concurrence dans
les marchés les plus rentables : la clientèle stable et même relativement
captive.
9993
Finalement, nous soutenons que l'établissement d'un facteur X qui reflète
les véritables gains de productivité dans l'industrie même si sa valeur est
relativement élevée pourrait inciter les ESLT à performer davantage constitue
l'élément fondamental du régime de plafonnement des prix.
9994
Un facteur X supérieur à l'inflation pourrait même occasionner des
réductions de tarifs, ce qui constituerait la meilleure façon de faire profiter
des mérites de la réglementation par plafonnement des prix aux consommateurs
résidentiels.
9995
L'Union des consommateurs soumet respectueusement ces éléments
d'argumentation au Conseil, et je remercie beaucoup monsieur le président, les
conseiller et conseillères et tous les membre du personnel du Conseil pour leur
précieux travail. Nous souhaitons de bonnes délibérations à tous et
toutes.
9996
LE PRÉSIDENT : Merci, Monsieur Provençal.
9997
Vous avez démontré votre maîtrise du sujet.
9998
Madame la Secrétaire ?
9999
THE SECRETARY: I now invite
counsel Macdonald, on behalf of BCOAPO et al to come
forward.
10000
Thank you.
‑‑‑ Pause
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
10001
MS MACDONALD: Good morning,
and thank you for the opportunity to provide comments about our views for the
next price cap regime that will go into effect in 2007.
10002
It has been a long morning and I will be filing written argument next
week, so my comments will be brief.
10003
As you know, our clients represent the most vulnerable of consumers, the
elderly, those who are disabled, persons on welfare and
tenants.
10004
Many of these consumers are on fixed incomes, therefore increases in the
cost of services which they need will take up a greater percentage of their
monthly income and often cannot be absorbed. For these Canadians affordability is
key.
10005
These consumers are also the least likely to have access to alternatives
for telephone service or to afford those alternatives. While many consumers want choice and are
willing to pay a premium for it, the consumers that I represent do not have that
luxury. What they need is continued
access to affordable telephone service.
10006
Basic telephone service continues to be an essential service. The outcome of this hearing will set the
rules that determines the cost of that service for the foreseeable
future.
10007
We recognize that as competition evolves and technological innovations
emerge, that the basic service line may also evolve and the product that
replaces it may look very different.
Perhaps it will be an access line, as was suggested by Bell, but for
today the provision of telephone service for a vast majority of Canadians
continues to be through the basic local service, which is the residential PES
line and which is provided to the majority of Canadians by the
ILECs.
10008
You have asked whether the objectives of the present price cap regime
should be changed. The Commission
designed the last price cap regime to achieve a number of objectives, including
rendering reliable and affordable services of high quality accessible to both
urban and rural customers.
10009
We have no objections to the objectives that were set in place by the
Commission in the last regime.
The objectives, including the one that I just stated, continue to be
appropriate going forward because the state of competition
remains uncertain.
10010
There is no guarantee that there will be competition for local phone
service.
10011
Currently, as I have said, the ILECs provide local phone service to a
majority of Canadians and over 90 percent across
Canada.
10012
Cable, which is emerging as the most promising form of competition is
still in its infancy. Currently
they serve approximately 4.5 percent of the market in B.C. and
Alberta. Certainly their recent
growth suggests that they have the ability to have a larger share of the market,
and they are optimistically predicting that amount to be 10 percent in
three years.
10013
However, that future is by no means certain or guaranteed and the future
of competition remains uncertain and unpredictable. We need only to look at what has
happened to mobile phones to see that this is so. The majority of consumers in Canada have
had the option of switching from a basic telephone line to a mobile phone for
the last five to 10 years, but only 5 to 6 percent of consumers in Alberta
and B.C. have done so. These
numbers speak loudly.
10014
Consumers do not see mobile phones as a suitable alternative for basic
telephone service.
10015
Then I come to the specifics of the price cap regime itself. We will be supporting Ottawa PIAC's
submissions with respect to the price cap formula.
10016
Specifically, we are supporting that there be no changes to the basket
structure and assignment of services.
10017
We also submit that the constraints for baskets of services should
continue to ply I‑X in order to lead to efficiency
improvements.
10018
In addition, the benefits of expanding economies of scope should be
shared by customers.
10019
We also support the constraints for individual
services.
10020
Last, we support that the deferral account should be discontinued and put
to the benefit of residential customers.
10021
We have some specific comments with respect to the uncapping
proposals of TELUS and Bell.
Neither of the tests that they have proposed
are adequate.
10022
First, we submit that both proposals are based on a false assumption that
the presence of competition equals competition. The market share achieved by the
alternative providers do not support this assumption.
10023
As I outlined above, in B.C. and Alberta the market share for mobile
phones is 5 to 6 percent, and for cable VoIP the market share across Canada
is 4.5 percent.
10024
Over 90 percent of customers do not have access to alternatives or
do not find that mobile phones or VoIP are acceptable alternatives. Therefore, it cannot be said that
competition exists.
10025
Second, the TELUS proposal is based on the false premise that a mobile
phone is a suitable alternative to local telephone
service.
10026
With respect to mobile, Dr. Roycroft outlined reasons that a mobile
phone is not a suitable alternative in his written evidence, including the
higher prices for mobile service, that mobiles are more difficult for elderly
and the disabled persons to use, and that multiple mobile phones would be needed
for a family to switch to that type of service.
10027
The evidence of CAC Manitoba and MSOS also provided further reasons
that mobile phones are not a realistic alternative, including that consumers
need a reasonable credit rating or must pay a large deposit and that
pay‑as‑you‑go plans are of limited use.
10028
Next, the over‑the‑top VoIP is not a suitable replacement. As explained by Dr. Roycroft,
consumers must have a broadband connection. It does not have a reliable 9‑1‑1
service and it does not work when the power goes out.
10029
The evidence of CAC Manitoba and MSOS also provided further reasons that
VoIP is not a suitable option, including that lower income consumers do not have
access to the necessary technology such as computers and the Internet, and that
consumers living in rentals or apartments cannot access that
technology.
10030
Last, costs must be looked at in assessing the two proposals from Bell
and TELUS.
10031
In B.C. and Alberta VoIP from Shaw costs $55 a month as opposed to the
cost of a local resident's phone, which ranges in B.C. from $23 to just under
$29. Clearly this is not
comparable.
10032
We do recognize for that Shaw service the monthly fee does include an
option added to it, but for those customers who do not want options or cannot
afford these options there is no choice, they continue to obtain and must obtain
their local telephone service from TELUS.
10033
From the TELUS evidence we did see that the average monthly spending for
a mobile phone is $79 per month.
Some portion of that was for long distance and for optional services, but
we were limited in the information that was released to
the intervenors.
10034
I believe that when the Commission reviews this confidential information,
they will find that mobile phone costs significantly more than local service
slides for a similar and comparable service.
10035
Accordingly, there are clear and tangible reasons that VoIP and mobile
phones are not suitable alternatives to basic residential
service.
10036
The pricing flexibility under the TELUS and Bell proposals gives them the
right to respond to competitive offers where they face competition and raise
them, or not, elsewhere. These will
be in areas where the consumers have no options and will be least likely to
afford an increase.
10037
The Commission has undertaken an extensive review of competition in the
local forbearance decision and has already determined what an LFR region will
look like.
10038
The evidence in this hearing has certainly showed the potential of
competition, but the outcome is uncertain and the timeframe is uncertain. Until we have the certainty, consumers
should be able to continue to rely on the protections of the price cap regime
and the oversight of the Commission.
10039
Additionally, the forbearance decision will allow flexibility for the
ILECs should competition fully develop before that time.
10040
Services under price cap should remain under price cap until
forborne.
10041
For these reasons, we are supportive of a four‑year term for the next
price cap period. During that time
the Commission will be able to assess whether and how competition has occurred,
particularly with respect to cable VoIP.
Before that time if real competition develops the forbearance decision
will come into play.
10042
As noted by the Manitoba branch of the Consumers Association of Canada
and the Manitoba Society of Seniors evidence, their written evidence, while the
price cap regime is certainly not perfect it provides protection for a
vulnerable segment of consumers in what is still essentially a monopoly
environment.
10043
The Commission can and should continue to protect these
consumers.
10044
This is the end of my comments and I wanted to thank the Commission, as
well as Commission staff, for facilitating our intervention in this
hearing.
10045
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you,
Ms Macdonald.
10046
THE SECRETARY: Thank you
very much.
10047
Last but not least, counsel Inlow for the City of
Calgary.
‑‑‑ Pause
ARGUMENT / PLAIDOIRIE
10048
MR. INLOW: Thank you,
Mr. Chair.
10049
I would like to start, if I may, by briefly commenting on an issue we
haven't had an opportunity to address before this point, which is the issue
about out of scope with respect to some of the evidence that has been given by
the City of Calgary.
10050
I wanted to clarify the positions that we are putting forward and
hopefully remove any cloud over that evidence without debating whether the fault
lies in the writing of the evidence or the interpretation of the
evidence.
10051
The Commission ruling was with respect to profit levels, rate of return
regulation and earnings sharing, and our submission is that clearly we are not
looking at returning to rate of return regulation, nor are we proposing earnings
sharing. To the extent we discuss
profit levels, it is in a context that, in my view, is legitimate with respect
to setting of an X factor level or an I‑X factor.
10052
Finally, in the briefing book, which I was not aware of, had not seen
prior to receiving the ruling of the Commission, I see where that ruling may
have come from. In there is also a
reference to an X factor being adjusted to allow the ILEC to earn its cost
of capital.
10053
We would submit that under price cap it is quite clear, I think, that the
factor of I‑X, which clearly is within the scope of this proceeding, is a factor
that in the evaluation of that between price cap regimes is a legitimate and
necessary endeavour of the Commission.
10054
To be clear, we are not proposing any retroactive changes to the
financial parameters of the current price cap regime. We are not proposing a different form of
regulation than price cap. We are
not proposing any re‑initialization of prices between the current and the next
price cap regime.
10055
What we are proposing, and is suggested in the evidence, is that ILEC
earnings over the current price cap period are a relevant consideration in
determining an X factor over the next price cap
regime.
10056
One need only look at the balance that the Commission is attempting to
establish in the price cap regime to realize that it is a balance between the
incumbents earning a fair return on their investment and their costs and
allowing customers to have the benefit of productivity costs that would
otherwise be realized in a competitive market.
10057
In fact, I would submit that our evidence in that respect does nothing
more than reflect the observations of the Commission in Decision 2004‑34,
where the Commission said that it recognized that ILEC financial returns will
need to be available for the purposes of review of the next
regime.
"Sufficient information must be
reported to allow the Commission to gauge the financial state of the ILECs in
order to ensure that the objectives of the price cap regime are being met." (As read)
10058
We submit that our evidence is very consistent with that
statement.
10059
I would also suggest that the Commission may have inadvertently
handcuffed themselves somewhat in that decision by relieving the ILECs of the
requirement to report on a split rate base basis, because that makes any
interpretation of those financial results that much more
difficult.
10060
We will, Mr. Chairman, be submitting written argument in this matter and
I am not proposing to try to touch on every subject that we will address on
that. We would prefer to focus on a
few matters that we think may be of particular interest to the
Commission.
10061
One of them clearly is the competitive presence test that is proposed by
TELUS. In looking at that test, it
strikes us that it is intended to set some kind of middle ground between the
discipline of the price cap regime and the discipline of the competitive market
and clearly has to be evaluated in some context.
10062
Our submission is that it clearly falls well short of any of the criteria
that the Commission set in its forbearance decision, and within the context of
the price cap regime is not a test which can be construed as protecting
consumers from the exercise of market power.
10063
The objectives of the price cap regime are to emulate a competitive
market from the perspective of three parties, being the ILECs and competitors
and customers, and emulates that market in the sense of both bringing to bear
the pressures and the benefits that competition should bring, whether
competition actually exists in fact or not.
10064
So in the absence of direct product and service competition, the primary
benefit that consumers look to receive from the price cap regime is the
pricing that would result from a competitive market and the pressure that exerts
to move toward incremental pricing.
10065
We must concede that the TELUS test has one single virtue, which is that
it is administratively clear and doesn't require any particular discretionary
adjudication, but that the presence of a facilities‑based competitor and the
presence of a non‑affiliated wireless competitor, do not meet the objectives of
the price cap regime, and certainly fall far short of any detailed analysis of
what the Commission was trying to achieve in the forbearance
decision.
10066
It, in our submission, comes down to an issue of when an ILEC can no
longer exercise market power, that being defined as the ability to impose
profitable and sustainable price increase in
the market.
10067
Now, the TELUS test for removal speaks of the presence of a
facilities‑based CLEC, whereas the forbearance decision indicates that an ILEC
must have suffered a 25 percent loss of market share.
10068
Without getting into the debate of wireless versus wireline substitution
or competition, whichever it may be, it is clear that mere presence has a number
of attributes, specifically it could be transitory, it could be unsuccessful in
making any significant market penetration, it could only be in a narrow segment
of the product or a narrow product offering, whereas the forbearance decision
indicates that an ILEC has to demonstrate to the Commission's satisfaction that
true rivalrous behaviour exists within the relevant
market.
10069
In fact, the Commission went on to indicate that their test with respect
to market share was intended to ensure that competition within the market would
be sustainable and not transitory, which is certainly a possibility where mere
presence of a facilities‑based CLEC is all that is required to trigger
it.
10070
Specifically, the attributes of rivalrous behaviour include, in the
Commission's deliberations, falling prices, expanding scope of competitor
activity in terms of products and innovation in those
products.
10071
So the underlying premise, in our submission, of the competitive presence
test is that the presence of competition means that market forces can be relied
on to replace Commission regulation in constraining upward movement of
prices.
10072
Our position is that the Commission should reject that premise and would
leave with the Commission the issue about how this test, which is clearly short
of forbearance, advances the natural development of market forces. Certainly one of the underlying
principles that TELUS is trying to put forward, is to say that in this
particular price cap regime we need to look at a regulation that moves us
seamlessly into a competitive environment.
10073
In our respectful view, the competitive presence test doesn't really
contribute to that seamless transition.
10074
I would also like to look at that competitive presence from the aspect of
a particular customer rather than on a conceptual level.
10075
Our focus isn't particularly about orphan customers and not even
specifically about what has been described as vulnerable customers, it is more
from the perspective of the proverbial Mrs. Grundy's ‑‑ although I
think she is a literary figure rather than a proverbial figure, but we will
leave it at that at the moment ‑‑ and try to in some ways envision what the
market will look like as it enters a developing competitive phase from the point
of view of that type of a customer who is more in the market for what I would
call fairly basic residential services.
10076
Now, it is interesting to see that in wireless competition, where
everyone started more or less on the same footing, there is a very wide variety
of competitive product offerings. I
think the evidence that has been in front of the Commission indicates fairly
clearly that there are all sorts of plans that are available that meet
individual needs of customers.
10077
We would submit that in respect of the wireline competition, which
started in a very different way, that is a long‑standing ILEC who is being
challenged slowly by CLECs who are trying to enter the market, that there isn't
nearly that type of robust product offering competition.
10078
The likelihood, in our submission, is that competition will probably
focus on fairly high margin services, or bundles of services, and that these
will be coming from cable providers.
I think it is clear, even from the TELUS evidence, that they are
indicating that basic CLEC resellers of local service aren't really the
competitive force in the market any more, that it is in fact cable companies who
are providing telephony as an incremental service over their
infrastructure.
10079
So one of the examples that came up in the evidentiary portion of this
hearing that was relevant in the Alberta area was that Shaw Cable was providing
a local telephony service that was priced at actually what would have been more
than double basic monthly telephone service. I believe it included a number of
optional services and features, those types of things which Commissioner Noël I
believe described as a "table d'hôte" offering.
10080
So when one analyzes that and sees that the nearest offering or
competitive offering for basic residential exchange service is more than double
what basic exchange is ‑‑ and to be fair that offering includes a number of
other features, being long distance and certainly optional calling features and
perhaps even international minutes, so I'm not trying to put forward a
proposition that this an apples to apples type of comparison, but nevertheless
that customer is faced with the fact that they are paying a certain amount for a
service and the next available option is stepping up more than double the
price.
10081
Now, the proposition that is put forward is that competition is going to
force prices downward, it is going to impose discipline in that respect, but
when one examines that it is very difficult to see in that specific scenario
where there is downward pressure on the ILEC with respect to costs for basic
residential service when the next competitor is that high above them in the
market.
10082
In fact, I think fundamental business might suggest, if anything, that
the perception of headroom in terms of the pricing of services for basic
residential is much more present than is the perception that there is downward
pressure on prices as a result of that competitive
offering.
10083
With respect to the I‑X component of the price cap, I am not at this
point proposing to make any detailed submissions with respect to the proper
amount of that factor, but would like to echo the comments of several who have
gone before me, that customers have, for a considerable amount of time under the
price cap regime, had the promised benefits of price cap disciplining prices
down in a market be deferred for other purposes and that in fact it is not
accrued directly to the customers who are basically paying into a deferral
account which is intended to achieve other purposes.
10084
Without repeating those comments as to the why and the wherefore of that,
simply say that in our submission it is perhaps time to say that the customers
are due to receive some of those benefits which have long been
deferred.
10085
I think it is important to note that a great deal of the motivation
behind maintaining prices at a certain level and using the deferral account was
to encourage the emergence of competition.
It is interesting to note, as I indicated earlier, that that competition
has not really materialized from basic service CLECs who are in the same local
service business and might have the same cost structures as a local service
provider, but in fact has developed from an alternate technology with a
completely different cost structure.
10086
So there isn't really any clear evidence to suggest that but for the
maintenance of costs in the deferral account that competition might not have
entered the market. It, in our
submission, has entered the market not because of the cost floor ‑‑ that is
there ‑‑ but because new technology has provided different cost structures
which are competitive without sort of duplicating an existing infrastructure for
a local service.
10087
I will leave our submissions at that,
Mr. Chairman.
10088
In addition to echoing the thanks of those who have gone before me to the
Commission and its staff, I would also like to add that I appreciate that the
Commission continues the tradition of holding an oral hearing on this very
important subject and resisting the temptation to go to a paper proceeding. I think it is very satisfying to be able
to participate in a hearing of that nature. I thank you.
10089
THE CHAIRPERSON: Thank you,
Mr. Inlow.
10090
Madame la secrétaire, do we have any final business to
transact?
10091
THE SECRETARY: Yes, we
do.
10092
For the record, before we conclude this hearing I would like to introduce
two new exhibits that were filed with us this morning by TELUS, and that is
TELUS Exhibit No. 16, Response to undertaking, TELUS Undertaking No. 2 regarding
high‑speed Internet services in TELUS' serving territory.
EXHIBIT NO. TELUS‑16: Response to undertaking, TELUS
Undertaking No. 2 regarding high‑speed Internet services in TELUS' serving
territory
10093
THE SECRETARY: The last one,
TELUS Exhibit No. 17, a follow‑up to TELUS' Undertaking No. 3 regarding
services with frozen rate treatment basket.
EXHIBIT NO. TELUS‑17: Follow‑up to TELUS' Undertaking
No. 3 regarding services with frozen rate treatment
basket
10094
THE SECRETARY: I believe
this concludes this hearing, Mr. Chairman.
10095
THE CHAIRPERSON: Ladies and
gentlemen, may I just thank you on behalf of the CRTC for your
participation in the hearing? I
appreciate your efficiency, your punctuality, your clarity, the large amount of
work that you have gone through to prepare your positions. I think that is the cost, or part of the
cost, of trying to develop an appropriate regulatory framework that can at least
be said to have reflected, in principle if not in practice, the disparate points
of view of different stakeholder. I
think they have been very well represented here by each of you and all of you
and we thank you very much for that.
10096
On behalf of my fellow panellists, I would like to thank the
staff of the CRTC for their hard work and their efficient operation of this
hearing.
10097
Thank you very much.
‑‑‑ Whereupon the hearing concluded at
1202 /
L'audience se termine à
1202
REPORTERS
_______________________
_______________________
Johanne Morin
Lynda Johansson
_______________________
_______________________
Jean Desaulniers
Fiona Potvin
_______________________
Sue